Earnings Quality in U.K. Private Firms

合集下载

earnings quality,insider trading and cost of capital

earnings quality,insider trading and cost of capital

DOI:10.1111/j.1475-679X.2005.00185.xJournal of Accounting ResearchVol.43No.5December2005Printed in U.S.A.Earnings Quality,Insider Trading,and Cost of CapitalD A V I D A B O O D Y,∗J O H N H U G HE S,∗A N D J I N G L I U†Received21October2003;accepted26April2005ABSTRACTPrevious research argues that earnings quality,measured as the unsigned abnormal accruals,proxies for information asymmetries that affect cost of capital.We examine this argument directly in two stages.In thefirst stage,we estimatefirms’exposure to an earnings quality factor in the context of a Fama-French three-factor model augmented by the return on a factor-mimicking portfolio that is long in low earnings qualityfirms and short in high earnings qualityfirms.In the second stage,we examine whether the earnings quality factor is priced and whether insider trading is more profitable forfirms with higher exposure to that factor.Generally speaking,wefind evidence consistent with pricing of the earnings quality factor and insiders trading more profitably infirms with higher exposure to that factor.1.IntroductionIn this paper,we examine two closely related issues regarding the cost of capital effects of asymmetric information:(1)whether the systematic component of asymmetric information is priced,and(2)whether privately informed traders earn greater profits when trading stocks with higher ex-posure to an asymmetric information risk factor.∗The authors are from the Anderson Graduate School of Management at UCLA;†Part of the paper was completed while Liu was visiting the Cheung Kong Graduate School of Business. We appreciate the research assistance of Mingshan Zhang and the helpful comments of an anonymous referee,Abbie Smith(the editor),Maureen McNichols,Robert Bushman,Paul Healy,Jun Pan,Krishna Palepu,Shyam Sunder and workshop participants at the Cheung Kong Graduate School of Business,Harvard Business School,Hong Kong University of Science and Technology,London Business School Stanford Summer Camp,University of Iowa and the2004 China International Finance Conference.651Copyright C ,University of Chicago on behalf of the Institute of Professional Accounting,2005652D.ABOODY,J.HUGHES,AND J.LIUThere is a growing empirical literature on both the cost of capital effects of asymmetric information(e.g.,Botosan[1997],Botosan and Plumlee[2002], Botosan,Plumlee,and Xie[2004],Healy,Hutton,and Palepu[1999], Francis et al.[2005],and Easley,Hvidkjaer,and O’Hara[2002])and the association of insider trading with asymmetric information(e.g.,Rozeff and Zaman[1998],Aboody and Lev[2000],Frankel and Li[2004],Piotroski and Roulstone[2005],and Ke,Huddart,and Petroni[2003]).1However, apart from a study by Bhattacharya and Daouk[2002]that investigates a correlation between enforced insider trading laws and cost of capital across countries,it remains to be determined if the prospect of privately informed trading is what drives a cost of capital effect of asymmetric information.It is plausible that the risk posed by privately informed trading may be fully diversifiable by uninformed traders,implying no cost of capital effect(e.g., Hughes,Liu,and Liu(2005]).This paper differs from prior literature on insider trading(e.g.,Frankel and Li[2004],Aboody and Lev[2000])in that we examine the relationship between insider trading and the systematic(priced)component of infor-mation risk,while the existing literature examines the relationship between insider trading andfirm-specific characteristics.This aspect is subtle but im-portant.For example,size is afirm-specific characteristic(idiosyncratic)and therefore cannot be a risk factor according to modernfinance theories such as the Capital Asset Pricing Model or the Arbitrage Pricing Theory(APT). To construct a risk factor related to size,one has to use factor-mimicking portfolios`a la Fama and French[1993].Finding evidence that insiders ex-ploit certainfirm-specific information characteristics has no implications for thefirm’s cost of capital,since this risk could be fully diversifiable.To relate insider trading to priced information risk(cost of capital),we must first isolate that risk,which is conventionally done via a factor model such as that of Fama and French[1993].Theoretical support for the exploitation of private information by in-formed traders as the explanation for a cost of capital effect of asymmetric information comes from Amihud and Mendelson[1986],Admati[1985], Dow and Gorton[1995],and Easley and O’Hara[2004].Other theories that do not rely on privately informed trading are based on incomplete informa-tion(e.g.,Merton[1986],Shapiro[2002])and estimation risk(e.g.,Barry and Brown[1985],Clarkson and Thompson[1990],and Clarkson,Guedes, and Thompson[1996]).Each of the above theories exploits the idea that the common knowledge assumption about the mean-variance matrix of asset payoffs adopted in neoclassical asset pricing theories may not hold,allowing for the prospect that investors will be differentially informed about the asset payoffs leading to a cost of capital effect if diversification is incomplete.A distinguishing characteristic of theories that rely on private information is 1Other studies by Seyhun[1998]and Lakonishok and Lee[2001]document profitability of insider trading without linking such profitability to specific measures of asymmetric infor-mation.EARNINGS QUALITY653 the exploitation of that information by informed traders.While we cannot rule out the possibility of multiple explanations for a cost of capital effect of earnings quality,afinding that insiders profit from trading on the priced component of earnings quality is consistent with an explanation based on asymmetric information.Our measure for identifyingfirms for which privately informed trading is likely to be more pronounced,and,hence,pose a greater asymmetric infor-mation risk to uninformed traders,is earnings quality defined as unsigned abnormal accounting accruals.2We chose earnings quality as our measure of information asymmetry for several reasons:thefindings of Francis et al. [2005]suggest that earnings quality is priced;relative to the cashflow com-ponent of earnings,accounting accruals are more prone to management discretion and manipulation,implying less private information may be pre-empted by earnings announcements;earnings quality is a ubiquitous con-struct that applies to all publicly tradedfirms;and unlike the probability of informed trading measure used by Easley,Hvidkjaer,and O’Hara[2002],an indirect measure of afirm’s information asymmetry derived from trade data, earnings quality is a relatively more direct measure of afirm’s information environment derived from fundamental accounting data contained in its financial statements.While we believe that it is reasonable to use unsigned abnormal accruals to proxy for information asymmetry,we are aware that abnormal accruals can be highly correlated with growth(Zhang[2005]). Hence,there could exist alternative interpretations of our empirical re-sults.3To be consistent with the idea of diversification in neoclassical asset pric-ing theory,following Francis et al.[2005]and Easley,Hvidkjaer,and O’Hara [2002],we estimate cost of capital using a factor model based on APT from ex post regressions.As in those studies,we use three factors recommended by Fama and French[1993]augmented by a fourth factor based on earn-ings quality to capture asymmetric information risk.If asymmetric informa-tion risk as measured by an earnings quality factor–mimicking portfolio is priced,then this risk should command a positive risk premium,and greater exposure to this risk as estimated from factor loadings should imply greater profits to privately informed trading.2Specifically,we employ four measures related to the unsigned value of afirm’s discretionary accruals as defined in Francis,et al.[2005].Two proxies are based on the modified Jones’model (Dechow,Sloan,and Sweeney[1995])and two are based on the Dechow and Dichev[2002] model.Other proxies appearing in the literature include the Association for Investment and Research’s assessment of corporate disclosure practices(Botosan[1997],Botosan and Plumlee [2002]),dispersion in analysts’earnings forecasts(Botosan,Plumlee,and Xie[2004]),and analysts’coverage(Healy,Hutton,and Palepu[1999]).3For example,if growth proxies for some priced risk factor,then the pricing result we docu-ment could be due to risk factors not related to information asymmetries.Further relating the cost of capital effect to informed trading profits helps to distinguish between these competing explanations,since it is difficult to establish a link between non–information based risk factors and informed trading profits.654D.ABOODY,J.HUGHES,AND J.LIULastly,we employ trades by corporate insiders(officers,directors,and principal stockholders)subsequently publicly disclosed to the Securities and Exchange Commission(SEC)as our measure of privately informed trading. While insiders are representative of informed traders,we envision that a similar information advantage extends to institutions and other professional traders,implying a sufficient impact on market orderflow to constitute a great enough potential risk to induce detectable risk premiums.Since these trade data are the measure of private information we use in assessing insider trading profitability,the natural window for purposes of estimating such profitability is from the trade date to the SECfiling date.4Accordingly, insider’s trading profits are measured by abnormal returns from the date of trade to one day afterfiling reports of those trades to the SEC after con-trolling for all risk factors including the asymmetric information risk factor. Since both the frequency of insider trades and the profitability to each trade contribute to the total profits earned by the insiders,we examine both aspects andfind both are positively correlated with thefirm’s exposure to the earnings quality(asymmetric information)risk factor.On the buy side, based on results for a hedge portfolio that is long in the highest quintile of asymmetric information risk factor loadingfirms and short in the lowest quintile,the difference in abnormal returns to insiders ranges from1.339% to3.344%for an average holding period of27days.Sell side results have the correct signs,but are smaller in magnitude and weaker in statistical signifi-cance,afinding consistent with the popularity of stock-based compensation and the prospect that insider sell transactions are more likely than buy trans-actions to be motivated by diversification(e.g.,Ofek and Yermack[2000]) and consumption.The results for the pricing effect of earnings quality are relatively weak but consistent.Wefind that while the quintile portfolios with highest exposure to the asymmetric information factor have statistically significant positive intercepts(i.e.,Jensen’s alphas)after controlling for the Fama and French [1993]risk factors,the quintile portfolios with the lowest exposure have alphas that are insignificantly different from zero.Results for the hedge portfolio have correct signs,with estimates ranging from0.992%per month to1.178%per month,but weak statistical significance levels,potentially due to noise in the system from the low-exposurefirms,or the diversification effect(e.g.,Hughes,Liu,and Liu[2005]).The combination of thesefindings is supportive of the conclusions that asymmetric information risk,as measured by thefirm’s exposure to an earnings quality factor–mimicking portfolio,has measurable pricing effects, and this risk is positively associated with expected insider trading profits.4Note that studies that explore insider trading profitability over longer windows(e.g.,Pi-otroski and Roulstone[2005]and Ke,Huddart,and Petroni[2003])condition their tests on the assumption that information revealed ex post was known to insiders ex ante.In contrast,we condition on just the portion of insiders’private information contained in trades reported to the SEC.Market efficiency in the semi-strong form dictates that one cannot predict abnormal returns to this information beyond thefiling date.EARNINGS QUALITY655 The remainder of this paper is organized as follows.In section2,we de-scribe how we measure earnings quality.In section3,we describe the sample data employed and provide descriptive statistics.Our empirical analyses of the cost of capital effects of asymmetric information risk and its association with insider trading are contained in section4.We conclude in section5 with a summary of our results and a discussion of how they relate to extant theory.2.Earnings QualityWe employ two approaches for deriving measures of earnings quality that are also used by Francis et al.[2005].Following Dechow,Sloan,and Sweeney [1995],one is based on estimates of abnormal accruals and the other,fol-lowing Dechow and Dichev[2002],is based on the extent to which working capital accruals map into cashflow realizations.Both approaches rely on accounting fundamentals to separate accruals into nondiscretionary(nor-mal)and discretionary(abnormal)components.Earnings quality is defined as the absolute value of the abnormal component.The larger the absolute value,the lower is earnings quality.Specifically,total accruals(TA j,t),total current accruals(TCA j,t),and cashflow from operations(CFO j,t)forfirm j and year t are calculated as shown below:TA j,t=( CA j,t− CL j,t− CASH j,t+ STDEBT j,t−DEPN j,t)TCA j,t=( CA j,t− CL j,t− CASH j,t+ STDEBT j,t)C FO j,t=NIBE j,t−TA j,twhere:CA j,t=firm j’s change in current assets(Compustat#4)in year t,CL j,t=firm j’s change in current liabilities(Compustat#5)in year t,CASH j,t=firm j’s change in cash(Compustat#1)in year t,STDEBT j,t=firm j’s change in short-term debt(Compustat#34)in year t,DEPN j,t=firm j’s depreciation and amortization expense (Compustat#14)in year t,andNIBE j,t=firm j’s net income before extraordinary items (Compustat#18)in year t.To estimate abnormal accruals(AA j,t)forfirm j in year t,we perform the following cross-sectional regression for each of Fama and French’s[1997] 48industry groups containing at least20firms in each year:TA j,t Asset j,t−1=k1,t1Asset j,t−1+k2,tREV j,tAsset j,t−1+k3,tPPE j,tAsset j,t−1+εj,t(1)656D.ABOODY,J.HUGHES,AND J.LIUwhere:REV j,t=firm j’s change in revenues(Compustat#12)in year t,PPE j,t=firm j’s gross value of property,plant,and equipment(Com-pustat#7)in year t,and we have deflated byfirm j’s totalassets in year t−1(Assets j,t−1,Compustat#6).We then use the industry-year-specific parameter estimates from(1)to estimatefirm-specific normal accruals(N A j,t)forfirm j in year t as a percent of lagged total assets;that is,NA j,t=ˆk1,t1Asset j,t−1+ˆk2,t( REV j,t− A R j,t)Asset j,t−1+ˆk3,tPPE j,tAsset j,t−1where:AR j,t=firm j’s change in accounts receivable(Compustat#2)in year t.5 In turn,abnormal accruals(AA j,t)forfirm j in year t areAA j,t=TA j,tAsset j,t−1−N A j,t.The absolute value of abnormal accruals(|AA j,t|)is thefirst earnings quality measure(EQ1),with larger values indicating lower earnings quality. Similar to total accruals,we estimate abnormal current accruals(ACA,jt) using the following variation of(1):TCA j,t Asset j,t−1=γ1,τ1Asset j,t−1+γ2,τREV j,tAsset j,t−1+v j,t.(2)We use the parameter estimates from equation(2)to calculate eachfirm’s normal current accruals as a percent of lagged assets,NCA j,t=ˆγ1,t1Asset j,t−1+ˆγ2,t( REV j,t− A R j,t)Asset j,t−1,and then calculate the abnormal component forfirm j in year t as:ACA j,t=TCA j,tAsset j,t−1−NCA j,t.Our second earnings quality measure(EQ2)is the absolute value of the abnormal current accruals(|AC A j,t|)calculated as shown above.Similar to EQ1,larger values of EQ2indicate poorer earnings quality.5Note that a prominent feature of the modified Jones model`a la Dechow,Sloan,and Sweeney[1995]is that changes in accounts receivables are included in revenues in the esti-mation of the model parameters,but are deducted from revenues in the event year.Dechow, Sloan,and Sweeney[1995]find this model exhibits the most power in detecting earnings management among other models they consider.EARNINGS QUALITY657 The two remaining measures of earnings quality proceed from estimates of total current accruals based on cashflows from operations,again employ-ing Fama and French’s[1997]48industries for each year with at least20firms:TCA j,t Aveasset j,t =θ0,j+θ1,jC FO j,t−1Aveasset j,t+θ2,jC FO j,tAveasset j,t+θ3,jC FO j,t+1Aveasset j,t+v j,t(3)where:Aveasset j,t=firm j’s average total assets over years t and t−1.Our third earnings quality measure(EQ3)is the absolute value of the firm’s residual(|ˆv j,t|)from equation(3),and our fourth earnings quality measure(EQ4)is the time-series standard deviation of thesefirm-specific residuals(σ(ˆv j,t,))calculated using a minimum offive residual observa-tions.Consistent with the construction of the other measures,larger abso-lute residuals and larger standard deviations of residuals are interpreted as lower earnings quality.3.Sample and Descriptive StatisticsWe gather accounting and cashflow data from Compustat and price data from the Center for Research in Security Prices(CRSP).The insider trad-ing data are obtained from the CDA/Investnet part of Thompson/First Call. The database contains all buy and sell transactions made by corporate insid-ers and reported to the SEC from January,1985,through November,2003. Corporate insiders are defined by the1934Securities and Exchange Act as corporate officers,directors,and owners of10%or more of any equity class of securities.We estimate each of the four earnings quality measures annually over the years1985to2003,yielding989,530firm-month observations for EQ1 and EQ2,910,477observations for EQ3,and614,981observations for EQ4.6 Table1contains descriptive statistics of the variables used in our analysis. It is evident from panel A of table1that sample distributions of EQ1and EQ2are highly skewed,with means being substantially higher than medi-ans.This suggests the presence of outliers in the positive extremes,caused partially by deflation using total assets when total assets for somefirms are close to zero.7Consistent with Francis et al.[2005],to reduce the influence of outliers in the calculation of correlations,we trimmed the sample at1% and99%in table1,panel B and panel C.In all other parts of our study, outlier treatments are not necessary since all analyses are done at a portfolio level.Inspecting insider buying and selling,wefind that insiders sell more6EQ measures are calculated on an annual basis.These annual measures are then matched with monthly returns to obtainfirm-month observations.7In section4.3,we discuss robustness checks on this issue.658D.ABOODY,J.HUGHES,AND J.LIUT A B L E1Summary StatisticsPanel A:Univariate distributionN Mean Median Std.Dev.Q1Q3 EQ1it989,5300.1100.0530.3410.0230.113 EQ2it989,5300.0890.0440.3160.0170.098 EQ3it910,4770.0730.0410.1310.0170.088 EQ4it614,9810.0730.0540.0730.0320.091 MV it989,530110981.68752.120.47385.9 RET it989,5300.009−0.0040.206−0.0880.078 BUY it51,9593.6902.0009.0691.0003.000 SELL it85,0758.7362.00076.936.0001.000 Panel B:Correlation matrix,Pearson above diagonal and Spearman belowEQ1EQ2EQ3EQ4EQ10.640.280.32EQ20.750.180.16EQ30.490.530.56EQ40.420.430.53Panel C:Mean and median coefficient estimates across9,966firms aRm–RF SMB HML EQMean Median Mean Median Mean Median Mean Median EQ10.910.850.680.700.300.250.490.08 EQ20.920.830.620.620.320.220.520.09 EQ30.880.810.590.600.320.230.510.10 EQ40.890.810.520.560.310.220.380.08 The sample consists of989,530observations from1985to2003.EQ1and EQ2are earnings quality measures based on the modified Jones model(Dechow,Sloan,and Sweeney[1995]).EQ1it is the absolute value of the abnormal total accruals and EQ2it is the absolute value of the abnormal current accruals.EQ3 and EQ4are earnings quality measures based on the Dechow and Dichev[2002]model.EQ3it is based on cross-sectional regressions and EQ4it is based on time-series regressions.MV it isfirm i’s market capitalization in millions at the end of calendar month t.RET it is monthly calendar return forfirm i.Afirm is classified as BUY if insiders’purchases exceed insiders’sales and SELL if insiders’sales exceed insiders’purchases.a Values in panel C calculated using the following four-factor model:R j,t−R f,t=αj+βj(R m,t−R f,t)+δj S MB t+σj HML t+φj E Q t+εj,twhere:R p,t is portfolio stock return;R f,t is the risk-free rate,measured as the one-month treasury bill rate; R m,t is the market portfolio return,measured using the CRSP value-weighted index;SMB t and HML t are the Fama and French[1993]size and market-to-book factor returns,respectively;EQ t is the hedge return going long in the low earnings qualityfirms and going short in the high earnings qualityfirms.The return window is monthly,and factor loadings are estimated using a time-series regression based on227months of data,from January,1985to November,2003.frequently than they buy,and the ratio of the sell to buy transactions is ap-proximately2to1.This is reasonable,because insiders,often compensated in stocks,have incentives to sell their company shares in order to diversify their personal wealth(e.g.,Ofek and Yermack[2000])and consume. Moving to the correlation matrix,wefind thefirst two earnings quality measures based on the modified Jones model(Dechow,Sloan,and Sweeney [1995])are highly correlated,with a Spearman rank order(SRO)correla-tion coefficient at0.75.However,the two measures based on Dechow and Dichev’s[2002]model are not as highly correlated(SRO=0.53),nor are they highly correlated with EQ1and EQ2.This suggests that EQ1and EQ2EARNINGS QUALITY659 are potentially capturing similar information constructs about thefirm,but that EQ3and EQ4are capturing somewhat distinct constructs.As a benchmark,similar to Francis et al.[2005],we estimate a four-factor asset-pricing model by adding an earnings quality factor to the Fama and French[1993]three-factor model.In particular,we perform time-series regressions for the following model:R j,t−R f,t=αj+βj(R m,t−R f,t)+δj SMB t+σj HML t+φj EQ t+εj,t(4) where:R j,t=firm j’s stock return;R f,t=the risk-free rate,measured as the one-month trea-sury bill rate;R m,t=the market portfolio return,measured using theCRSP value-weighted index;SMB t and HML t=the Fama and French[1993]size and market-to-bookfactor returns,respectively;andEQ t=the hedge portfolio return going long in the ex-treme quintile of low earnings qualityfirms and goingshort in the extreme quintile of high earnings qualityfirms.8In order to make sure that observations pertaining to all variables on the right-hand side of equation(4)are publicly available ex ante,we construct the EQ factor–mimicking portfolio using the realizations of earning quality measures in the precedingfiscal year.We run time-series regressions on each firm using data from January,1985,to November,2003.The mean and median factor loadings are reported in panel C of ta-ble1.The results are broadly consistent with those reported in Francis et al.[2005].The consistently positive factor loading on the earnings quality factor–mimicking portfolio indicates that,like the Fama and French[1993] factors,asymmetric information risk seems to be priced by the market.How-ever,since positive loadings do not in themselves imply a nonzero risk pre-mium,we move to the next section to investigate whether the asymmetric information risk,as captured by our earnings quality proxies,is priced.4.Empirical Analyses4.1EARNINGS QUALITY,INSIDER TRADING,AND ABNORMAL RETURNSIn this section,we establish that the earnings quality measures are effective proxies for information asymmetry that serves as a source of trading advan-tage exploited by corporate insiders.Because the purpose of this section is8We obtained the Fama and French[1993]factor-mimicking portfolio returns from Ken French’s Web site:/pages/faculty/ken.french/ data library.html.660D.ABOODY,J.HUGHES,AND J.LIUto verify whether the EQ measures proxy for information used by corporate insiders,we calculate the EQ measures contemporaneously based on annual financial statements,and these measures are only partially observable to the investing public from previously released quarterlyfinancial reports.Corpo-rate insiders are hypothesized to know more about these measures than the general public.In section4.2and4.3,where we investigate the systematic component of information risk,we only use publicly available information and construct the factor-mimicking portfolios based on EQ measures of the precedingfiscal years.To begin,in each year,we partitionfirms into quintile portfolios based on contemporaneous estimates of earnings quality and construct a hedge portfolio that is long in the lowest quintile of earnings qualityfirms and short in the highest quintile.Similar to prior studies on insider trading(e.g., Aboody and Lev[2000],Piotroski and Roulstone[2005],and Ke,Huddart, and Petroni[2003]),we use the earnings quality measures as proxies for information available to insiders,but not to outside investors.To the extent that these measures are effective proxies for information asymmetry,we should be able to detect differential insider trading profits across the quintile portfolios,that is,insider trading profits should be negatively correlated with earnings quality measures.We examine insider trading by further partitioning each quintile portfolio based on earnings quality into thosefirms in which monthly insider trades are net buys and net sells and estimating abnormal returns using the Fama and French[1993]three-factor model applied to excess portfolio returns:9 R p,t−R f,t=αp+βp(R m,t−R f,t)+δp SMB t+σp HML t+εp,t.(5) To measure insider profits,in each month,we compute afirm-specific mean return from the transaction dates of insiders’trades to one day af-ter thefiling date of those transactions with the SEC.Thesefirm-specific transaction-to-reporting returns are averages over all the individual insider trades that occurred during the month.We take the average of trades be-cause in manyfirm-months insiders have multiple trades.In afirm-month in which insiders trade at opposite directions,we still take the average transaction-to-reporting returns,and the average return is classified as a buy (sell)if the net transaction is a buy(sell)in number of shares.Firm-months with no trades are excluded from the analysis.10We group insider trading ac-cording to the transaction dates rather thanfiling dates,for example,if two trades occurred in the same calendar month,and one trade isfiled within that month and the other trade isfiled in the subsequent month,we assign both trades to the former month.This grouping causes some inevitable cal-endar time mismatching between components of portfolio returns,as well 9We classify afirm as a net buyer if the number of shares bought by all insiders during the month exceeds the number of shares sold.The number of transactions,number of shares,and total value of transactions are highly correlated.Replication of the tests with dollar value of transactions yields very similar results to those derived from the number of shares.10We examine the no-trade sample as a benchmark.Results are discussed in section4.3.as mismatching between portfolio returns and Fama-French factor returns.We believe potential biases from such mismatching are minimal since themean interval between transactions andfiling dates is only27days.Suchmismatching may be viewed as a source of noise,and,therefore,likely toreduce the power of tests,implying a bias againstfinding significant results.We run time-series regressions for these portfolios based on227monthsof data,from January,1985to November,2003,to estimate the intercept andfactor loadings.Because insider buying and selling are measured monthly,ineffect our portfolios are rebalanced every month.In addition to the monthlyrebalancing due to insider trading,the portfolios are also rebalanced by theend of eachfiscal year to reflect changes in earnings quality.Inasmuch asthe estimated intercepts for thefive-quintile portfolios are generally(withminor exceptions)monotone for all four earnings quality measures,to savespace,we only report the results for the extreme portfolios and the hedgeportfolio in table2.The factor loadings on the three Fama and French[1993]risk factorsare qualitatively similar to the benchmark case reported in panel C oftable1.However,they differ in magnitude.Some differences are expectedsince table2is based on portfolio regressions while panel C of table1isbased onfirm-by-firm regressions.The most notable and systematic differ-ences in portfolio loadings occur for the hedge portfolios.These loadingson the three Fama and French[1993]factors are,for the most part,closerto zero,as we would expect given the long and short trading strategy of thehedge portfolios.Our primary interest is with Jensen’s alphas(intercepts),αp,as a measure of excess returns for each combination of insider trans-action type,earnings quality portfolio,and earnings quality measure,aftercontrolling for the Fama and French[1993]risk factors.As expected,the estimated intercepts from time-series regressions of thedifference in return between low earnings qualityfirms and those with highearnings quality on the three systematic factors are all positive when insidersbought shares.For the hedge portfolio,the estimated intercept for EQ1is1.342%(t-statistic=2.16),for EQ2is2.408%(t-statistic=3.00),for EQ3is1.282%(t-statistic=1.88),and for EQ4is0.912%(t-statistic=1.04).11While the results for EQ1and EQ2are statistically significant at conven-tional levels,the result for EQ3is only marginally significant,and the resultfor EQ4is insignificant,suggesting thefirst three measures are better prox-ies for information advantages experienced by insiders.Another plausibleexplanation for the insignificant results for EQ4is the material reductionin sample size that occurs because the estimation of EQ4requiresfive yearsof data.1211The t-statistics are conventional measures based on the assumption of zero serial depen-dence.In all tests here,and later in table4,we also calculate standard errors using the Newey-West procedure to adjust for potential serial dependence.The results are quite close due to negligible serial dependence in stock returns at the monthly frequency.12Note that the number of observations per regression is considerably reduced from those indicated for our full original sample by partitioning on earnings quality and direction of insider trades.。

AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF CROSS-LISTING DECISIONS AND THEIR IMPACT ON EARNINGS QUALITY

AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF CROSS-LISTING DECISIONS AND THEIR IMPACT ON EARNINGS QUALITY

310
SBR 61 July 2009 310-330
EARNINGS QUALITY
quality. Cross-listing firms will either increase or decrease their level of earnings management, but firms remaining in the home country will generally decrease their level of earnings management after other firms have made cross-listing decisions. This result is driven by the information conveyed to capital market participants by the cross-listing decision. Economic incentives for earnings management result from contracts written in terms of accounting numbers and from expected capital market reactions to financial reporting. Empirically, earnings management appears to be driven more often by capital market considerations than by contractual arrangements (Graham, Harvey, and Rajgopal (2005); Dechow and Skinner (2000)). Consistent with these findings, in this paper I analyze earnings management in a capital market context. I follow an approach similar to that of Fischer and Verrecchia (2000), Ewert and Wagenhofer (2005), and Guttman et al. (2006). I complement their work by explicitly considering an international context in which an entrepreneur has the possibility to cross-list to another country and to voluntarily subject herself to its stricter financial reporting regime. My paper’s purpose is twofold. To derive insights into the economics of cross-listing decisions, I combine a model of earnings management with elements of a standard signalling model. I assume that accounting manipulation is more costly when enforcement is stricter, and I derive preferences for one financial reporting regulatory system over another within this setting. From the business perspective, I apply the idea of cross-listing as a bonding device. I examine its implications for international earnings quality by deriving propositions about the effects of cross-listing on the level of earnings management both of the cross-listing firms and of the firms that choose not to cross-list. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the literature on cross-listing and on earnings management. In Section 3 I present the general model of earnings management and derive comparative statics of entrepreneurs’ expected utility under different levels of financial reporting enforcement. In Section 4 I build on these insights and extend the general model by allowing firms to influence the regulatory system they are subject to via cross-listing. Section 5 concludes. 2 R ELATED L ITERATURE The accounting literature generally assumes that the reasons for earnings management lie in contractual relationships and expected capital market reactions to financial reporting. Limitations on compensation and debt contracting may induce earnings manipulation (Arya, Glover, and Sunder (1998)). Healy (1985) shows that accrual policies of managers are related to incentives stemming from their bonus contracts. Guidry, Leone, and Rock (1999) find similar results using business unit-level data. Earnings management may also be used in order to avoid violating debt covenants. Beatty and Weber (2003) show that the provisions of a firm’s debt contract affect its accounting choices and that the accounting method choices of firms with such contracts are more likely to be income-increasing. Sweeney (1994) finds that firms approaching debt-covenant default respond with incomeincreasing accounting changes.

Earnings Quality

Earnings Quality
0.9 0.8 Estimated Persistence Parameter 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.30 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0
Sales Operating Operating Pretax Income Earnings Income Income Income After Before Before Before Depreciation Special ItemsExtraordinary Depreciation Items CFO FCF CFF CFI
Source: Nissim and Penman (2001)
Stage of life cycle and persistence: RNOA growth
Figure 4.2: Return on Net Operating Asset (RNOA) over time. Deciles formed on the magnitude of RNOA.
0.85 0.76 0.76 0.72 0.71 0.71 0.65
0.41
0.25
2. Earnings and intrinsic value

Do earnings map into value better than do cash flows?

Measuring intrinsic value
1. 2.
Forecast earnings Make stock recommendations
1.
2.
Earnings are higher quality: The more predictable and easier to forecast; AND The better they map into intrinsic value

Adjustments, Financial Statements, and the Quality of Earnings

Adjustments, Financial Statements, and the Quality of Earnings

Debit
Credit
Cash Accounts receivable Inventory Equipment Accumulated depreciation - equip.
$
3,900
4,985
3,300
4,800
$
1,440
Furniture and fixtures
6,600
Accumulated depreciation - furn. & fix.
6,600
27,500 6,300
Totals
$
57,385 $
Credit
1,440 2,200 2,985 4,000 10,000 1,760 35,000
57,385
4-7
Matrix, Inc. Unadjusted Trial Balance
At December 31, 2009
Description
Credit
1,440 2,200 2,985 4,000 10,000 1,760 35,000
57,385
4-9
Unearned Revenues
End of accounting period.
Cash received.
Revenues earned.
Example includes rent received in advance (an unearned revenue).
4-16
Prepaid Expenses
After we post the entry to the T-accounts, the account balances look like this:

Effects of Audit Quality on Earnings Management and Cost of Equity Capital Evidence from China

Effects of Audit Quality on Earnings Management and Cost of Equity Capital Evidence from China
1
constrains managerial reporting discretion and therefore reduces information risk. We measure managerial reporting discretion and information risk by the magnitude of discretionary accruals and use it to assess the effect of audit quality (Becker et al. 1998). We also utilize the ex ante cost of equity capital as a yardstick to assess the valuation implications of audit quality, as do Khurana and Raman (2004). If high audit quality reduces information risk, which is non-diversifiable, it should translate to a tangible benefit in the form of lower cost of equity capital. Our analyses are based on a sample of 3,310 firm-year observations with sufficient data on the China Securities Markets and Accounting Research Database from 2001 to 2004. Consistent with prior research, we use audit firm size as a proxy for audit quality. We classify the eight largest audit firms (Top 8), which include the international Big 4 and the four largest Chinese firms, as high audit quality providers and all other audit firms (non-Top 8) as low audit quality providers. We use absolute and signed performance-matched modified Jones model discretionary accruals to measure earnings management. We measure ex ante cost of equity capital using the industry method introduced by Gebhardt, Lee, and Swaminathan (2001) and the PEG ratio method proposed by Easton (2004). We find a significantly lower level of earnings management for NSOEs audited by Top 8 auditors than for NSOEs audited by non-Top 8 auditors. In contrast, we do not observe a significant corresponding difference in the level of earnings management for SOEs. Additionally, we find a significantly greater reduction in earnings management from hiring Top 8 versus non-Top 8 auditors for NSOEs than for SOEs. We obtain consistent results when we use absolute discretionary accruals and income-increasing discretionary accruals to measure earnings management. Our analysis indicates that the effect of audit quality on cost of equity capital is not uniform across SOEs and NSOEs. Cost of equity capital is significantly lower for NSOEs audited by Top 8 auditors than for NSOEs audited by non-Top 8 auditors, but not

高盛财经词典—英汉对照

高盛财经词典—英汉对照

高盛财经词典—英汉对照A1. accounting (会计)The process of recording, summarizing, and analyzing financial transactions in order to prepare financial statements and reports.会计是记录、汇总和分析财务交易的过程,以便编制财务报表和报告。

2. asset (资产)Anything that has a value and is owned by an individual, company, or organization.任何具有价值并由个人、公司或组织拥有的物品。

3. audit (审计)An independent examination and verification of an organization’s financial records and sta tements by a qualified person or firm.由合格的个人或公司对组织的财务记录和报表进行独立检查和核实。

B1. balance sheet (资产负债表)A financial statement that shows a company’s assets, liabilities, and shareholders’ equity at a specific point in time.资产负债表是一份显示公司在特定时间点的资产、负债和股东权益的财务报表。

2. bear market (熊市)A market condition in which prices of securities are falling or expected to fall, often characterized by widespread pessimism and selling.指证券价格下跌或预计下跌的市场状况,通常以广泛的悲观情绪和抛售行为为特征。

The Quality of Accruals and Earnings_ The Role of Accrual Estimation errors

The Quality of Accruals and Earnings_ The Role of Accrual Estimation errors

THE ACCOUNTING REVIEWV ol.77Supplement2002pp.35–59The Quality of Accruals and Earnings:The Role of AccrualEstimation ErrorsPatricia M.DechowUniversity of MichiganIlia D.DichevUniversity of MichiganABSTRACT:This paper suggests a new measure of one aspect of the qualityof working capital accruals and earnings.One role of accruals is to shift oradjust the recognition of cashflows over time so that the adjusted numbers(earnings)better measurefirm performance.However,accruals require as-sumptions and estimates of future cashflows.We argue that the quality ofaccruals and earnings is decreasing in the magnitude of estimation error inaccruals.We derive an empirical measure of accrual quality as the residualsfromfirm-specific regressions of changes in working capital on past,present,and future operating cashflows.We document that observablefirm charac-teristics can be used as instruments for accrual quality(e.g.,volatility of ac-cruals and volatility of earnings).Finally,we show that our measure of accrualquality is positively related to earnings persistence.Keywords:quality of accruals;earnings quality;estimation errors;earningspersistence.Data Availability:Data are available from sources identified in the paper.I.INTRODUCTIONT his paper suggests a new measure of one aspect of the quality of working capital accruals and earnings.The measure is based on the observation that accruals shift or adjust the recognition of cashflows over time,so that the adjusted numbers (earnings),better measurefirm performance(e.g.,see Statement of Accounting Concepts We thank workshop participants at The University of Arizona,University of Chicago,Columbia University, Indiana University,University of Michigan,The Accounting Review Conference on Quality of Earnings held at Emory University,the2001Big Ten Research Conference,and especially Dan Collins,Bob Lipe,Mort Pincus, Katherine Schipper,Peter Wysocki,and two anonymous reviewers.Professor Dechow acknowledgesfinancial support provided by the Michael A.Sakkinen Research Scholar Fund at the University of Michigan Business School.Professor Dichev acknowledges thefinancial support of the Sanford Robertson Assistant Professorship in Business Administration and the Norman Auerbach PricewaterhouseCoopers Faculty Fellowship.3536The Accounting Review,2002Supplement No.1,FASB1978,para.44).For example,recording a receivable accelerates the recog-nition of a future cashflow in earnings,and matches the timing of the accounting recognition with the timing of the economic benefits from the sale.However,accruals are frequently based on assumptions and estimates that,if wrong,must be corrected in future accruals and earnings.For example,if the net proceeds from a receivable are less than the original estimate,then the subsequent entry records both the cash collected and the correc-tion of the estimation error.We argue that estimation errors and their subsequent corrections are noise that reduces the beneficial role of accruals.Therefore,the quality of accruals and earnings is decreasing in the magnitude of accrual estimation errors.Our empirical measure of accrual quality is the extent to which working capital accruals map into operating cash flow realizations,where a poor match signifies low accrual quality.The intuition behind this measure is available in both theoretical and practical texts that observe that the beneficial role of accruals is reduced by various limitations,including estimation errors.For example,Palepu et al.(2000)discuss estimation errors as a factor that reduces accounting quality,and suggest that estimation accuracy depends onfirm char-acteristics like complexity of transactions and predictability of thefirm’s environment.We develop this existing intuition into a practical measure of accrual and earnings quality.Our approach to estimating the quality of accruals is related to two streams of research. First,several studies document the benefits of the accrual process,finding that earnings is a better measure of performance than the underlying cashflows(e.g.,Dechow1994; Dechow et al.1998;Liu et al.2002).We build on this evidence by exploring the trade-offs inherent in the accrual process.Second,a number of studies use models of‘‘discre-tionary accruals’’to investigate the manipulation of accruals to achieve earnings manage-ment goals(see Healy and Wahlen[1999]for a recent review).These studies focus on the opportunistic use of accruals to window-dress and mislead users offinancial statements. This stream of research suggests that managerial intent affects the incidence and magnitude of accrual estimation errors.In contrast,we argue that even in the absence of intentional earnings management, accrual quality will be systematically related tofirm and industry characteristics.This dis-tinction is important because such characteristics are likely to be both observable and recurring(e.g.,the volatility of operations is systematically related to the propensity to make estimation errors)as compared to the determinants of managerial opportunism that are often unobservable and/or sporadic(e.g.,before stock offerings).For our purposes,we do not attempt to disentangle‘‘intentional’’estimation errors from unintentional errors be-cause both imply low-quality accruals and earnings.We develop a model that examines the origination and reversal of working capital accruals in a stylizedfirm.The model embodies the intuition that the timing of thefirm’s economic achievements and sacrifices often differs from the timing of the related cashflows, and that the benefit of accruals is to adjust for these cashflow timing problems.However, the model also reveals that the benefit of using accruals comes at the cost of including accrual components that initiate and correct estimation errors.We focus on working capital accruals and operating cashflows for tractability:the initiation and reversal of these accruals occurs within a year.Our measure of accrual estimation errors is the residuals fromfirm-specific regressions of changes in working capital on last year,present,and one-year ahead cashflows from operations.These residuals are unrelated to cashflow realizations,and include the estimation errors and their reversals.The standard deviation of these residuals is ourfirm-specific measure of quality of accruals and earnings,where a higher standard deviation signifies lower quality.We illustrate the usefulness of our analysis in two ways.First,we explore the relation between our measure of accrual quality andfirm characteristics.The nature of the accrualDechow and Dichev—The Quality of Accruals and Earnings 37process suggests that the magnitude of estimation errors will be systematically related to business fundamentals like the length of the operating cycle and variability of operations.We find that accrual quality is negatively related to the absolute magnitude of accruals,the length of the operating cycle,loss incidence,and the standard deviation of sales,cash flows,accruals,and earnings,and positively related to firm size.Our results suggest that these observable firm characteristics can be used as instruments for accrual quality.This is im-portant because the regression-based estimation of accrual quality demands long time-series of data and the availability of subsequent cash flows,which makes it costly or infeasible for certain practical applications (e.g.,quality-of-accruals-based trading strategies).Second,we illustrate the usefulness of our analysis by exploring the relation between our measure of accrual quality and earnings persistence.Firms with low accrual quality have more accruals that are unrelated to cash flow realizations,and so have more noise and less persistence in their earnings.Indeed,we find a strong positive relation between accrual quality and earnings persistence.However,our measure of accrual quality is theoretically and empirically related to the absolute magnitude of accruals,and Sloan (1996)documents that the level of accruals is less persistent than cash flows.Probing further,we find that accrual quality and level of accruals are incremental to each other in explaining earnings persistence,with accrual quality the more powerful determinant.The remainder of the study is organized as follows.Section II presents our model of accrual quality.Section III describes the sample and provides descriptive statistics.Section IV derives the empirical measure of accrual quality and explores the relation between accrual quality and both firm characteristics and earnings persistence.Our conclusions are provided in Section V .II.THEORETICAL MEASURE OF ACCRUAL AND EARNINGS QUALITY Model of AccrualsOur model of accruals focuses on working capital accruals because cash flow realiza-tions related to working capital generally occur within one year,making both the theory and the empirics more tractable.While the intuition about errors in estimation applies to all accruals,the long lags between noncurrent accruals and cash flow realizations practically restrict the application of our approach to only short-term accruals.We build our accrual framework around the observation that earnings equals cash flows plus accruals,E ϭCF ϩAccruals.Cash flows for any period t can be categorized into three groups:SymbolName CF t t Ϫ1Cash Collections or Payments of Amounts Accrued at t Ϫ1(net)CF t tCurrent Cash Flows (net)CF t t ϩ1Cash Flows Deferred to t ϩ1(net)From an accounting perspective,for each cash flow,the two important events are the receipt or disbursement of the cash flow and the recognition of that cash flow in earnings (as revenue or expense).The subscript refers to the period the cash flow is received or disbursed,and the superscript refers to the period the cash flow is recognized in earnings.For example,CF t t–1denotes that the cash flow occurs after the corresponding amount is recognized in earnings (e.g.,collection of an accounts receivable).CF t t refers to cash flows received or paid in the same period as the cash flows are recognized in earnings.Finally,CF t t ϩ1refers to cash received or paid before the revenue or expense is recognized in earn-ings,such as cash payments for inventory.38The Accounting Review,2002Supplement Summing up,total cash flow for period t is:t Ϫ1t t ϩ1CF ϭCF ϩCF ϩCF (1)t t t t The accounting system provides for accruals,temporary adjustments that shift the rec-ognition of cash flows over time.When recognition of a cash flow is shifted,two accrual entries are created,an opening and a closing accrual.The opening accrual is initiated when either (1)revenue or expense is recognized before the cash is received or paid or (2)cash is received or paid before it is recognized in earnings.The closing accrual is recorded when the other element of this pair has occurred and reverses the accrual portion of the original entry.When cash flows occur after the corresponding revenues and expenses are recognized in earnings,managers must estimate the amount of cash to be received or paid in the future.To the extent that cash flow realizations differ from their accrual estimates,the opening accrual will contain an estimation error that is corrected by the closing accrual.We incorporate this intuition in our model using the following notation for opening and closing accruals related to future cash flows:NameAccrual ϭAmount Accrual for future collectionsA CFt ϩ1/t O ϭCF t ϩ1t ϩεt ϩ1t and payments—OpeningSame sign as related cashflowAccrual for future collectionsA CFt /t–1C ϭ–CF t t–1–εt t–1and payments—ClosingOpposite sign of related cashflow For accruals,the subscript refers to the corresponding cash flow,while the superscript indicates opening or closing accruals.For example,A CFt ϩ1/t O is an opening accrual related to cash flow CF t ϩ1t .The opening accrual at time t,which reflects the expectation of the t ϩ1cash flow,is equal to the actual t ϩ1cash flow plus an error term that reflects the difference between the accrual expectation and the cash flow realization.We assume that all accruals are resolved within one period so the closing accrual for cash collections and payments at time t offsets the opening accrual from t Ϫ1.The closing accrual is equal to the actual cash flow collected or paid in t plus an error term equal to the difference between last period’s expectation and this period’s cash flow realization.Thus,each period’s total accruals contain an estimation error in the opening accruals (the actual value of which is determined next period,εt ϩ1t )plus a realized error in the closing accruals (determined from current period cash flow realizations,εt t–1).1We next provide the notation for situations where cash flows are received or paid before their recognition in earnings.In this case,the accounting system recognizes the amount of 1We assume that estimation errors are independent of each other and of the magnitude of the cash flow realizations,within the firm .While estimation errors can be correlated across firms (e.g.,bad debt expense proves to be systematically understated in a recession),cross-firm dependencies are not a problem for our approach because our tests are at the firm level.Our approach also ignores estimation errors that are correlated at the firm level (e.g.,an optimistic manager systematically underestimates expenses).This is one of the limitations of our approach.Dechow and Dichev—The Quality of Accruals and Earnings 39the cash flow either as deferred revenue (for cash inflows)or a deferred cost (for cash outflows):NameAccrual ϭAmount Accrual that defers theA CFt /t ϩ1O ϭ–CF t t ϩ1recognition of cash flows—OpeningOpposite sign of related cash flowAccrual that defers theA CFt–1/t C ϭCF t–1trecognition of cash flows—ClosingSame sign as related cash flow As before,accrual subscripts refer to the corresponding cash flows,while superscripts indicate opening or closing accruals.For example,A CFt /t ϩ1O is an opening accrual related to cash flow CF t t ϩ1.Since deferred cash flows occur before recognition,these accruals contain no estimation error (in the sense of our model).For example,an inventory purchase initiates a positive accrual equal to the purchase price cash outflow,while the sale of the inventory triggers a negative accrual equal in magnitude to the initial cash flow.Appendix A provides a discussion and examples of whether and how our model detects accrual estimation errors depending on the timing of related accruals and cash flows.Using Expression (1),and defining total accruals as the sum of opening and closing accruals,allows us to express earnings as:E ϭCF ϩAccruals t t tt Ϫ1t t ϩ1O C O C E ϭ(CF ϩCF ϩCF )ϩ(A ϩA ϩA ϩA )t t t t CFt ϩ1/t CFt /t Ϫ1CFt /t ϩ1CFt Ϫ1/t t Ϫ1t t ϩ1t t t Ϫ1t Ϫ1t ϩ1t E ϭ(CF ϩCF ϩCF )ϩ(CF ϩεϪCF ϪεϪCF ϩCF )(2)t t t t t ϩ1t ϩ1t t t t Ϫ1Re-arranging yields:t t t t t Ϫ1E ϭCF ϩCF ϩCF ϩεϪε.(3)t t Ϫ1t t ϩ1t ϩ1t Equation (3),which presents earnings as the sum of past,present,and future cash flows plus an adjustment for estimation errors and their correction,expresses the main intuition of the paper.The intertemporal shifting of cash flows reflected in the cash flow terms of Equation (3)alleviates the timing problems of using current cash flows as a measure of performance.However,this benefit comes at the cost of using estimates,with the result that earnings includes both errors in estimates and their corrections.Both errors and error corrections reduce the quality of earnings as a measure of performance.Most of our predictions about the relations between the variables in Equations (2)and(3)concern relations studied by existing research.We include them to show that our model embodies the intuitive and well-known properties of earnings,cash flows,and accruals,and as a benchmark and link to existing ing Equations (2)and (3)allows one to make the following predictions:a)Corr(E t ,CF t )ϭϩb)Corr(E t ,Accruals t )ϭϩc)Corr(CF t ,Accruals t )ϭϪ40The Accounting Review,2002SupplementThese predictions,concerning the correlations between contemporaneous earnings,cash flows,and accruals,have been confirmed by,for example,Dechow (1994)and Dechow et al.(1998).d)Corr(E t ,CF t ϩ1)ϭϩe)Corr(Accruals t ,CF t ϩ1)ϭϩThese correlations suggest that earnings,and particularly its accrual portion,anticipates future cash flows.This result has been confirmed by,for example,Finger (1994)and Barth et al.(2001).Note that these predictions are based on ceteris paribus assumptions,so there is a need to control for possible confounding factors.Specifically,in examining the relation between current accruals and future cash flows,one needs to control for the confounding effect of current cash flows.The reason is that current accruals are negatively related to current cash flows,and future cash flows are (empirically)positively related to current cash flows.f)Corr(E t ,CF t Ϫ1)ϭϩg)Corr(Accruals t ,CF t Ϫ1)ϭϩTo our knowledge,the prediction that current earnings,and particularly its accrual portion,is positively correlated with past cash flows is novel.The intuition is that accruals defer the recognition of some past cash flows into current earnings.As mentioned above,in examining this prediction,it is important to control for the confounding effect of current cash flows.Deriving an Empirical Measure of Quality of AccrualsWe obtain an expression for accruals at time t by rearranging the accrual portion of earnings in Equation (2):t t ϩ1t Ϫ1t t t Ϫ1A ϭCF –(CF ϩCF )ϩCF ϩεϪε.(4)t t Ϫ1t t t ϩ1t ϩ1t Equation (4)conveys that (1)accruals are temporary adjustments that delay or antici-pate the recognition of realized cash flows plus an estimation error term;(2)accruals are negatively related to current cash flows and positively related to past and future cash flows;and (3)the error term captures the extent to which accruals map into cash flow realizations,and can be used as a measure of accrual and earnings quality.To derive practical measures of working capital accrual quality,we use the following firm-level time-series regression:⌬WC ϭb ϩb *CFO ϩb *CFO ϩb *CFO ϩε.(5)t 01t Ϫ12t 3t ϩ1t Relative to Equation (4),our measure of accruals is changes in working capital,and our proxies for cash flows related to accruals is cash flow from operations (CFO).The residuals from the regression reflect the accruals that are unrelated to cash flow realizations,and the standard deviation of these residuals is a firm-level measure of accrual quality,where higher standard deviation denotes lower quality.The theoretical specification in Equation (4)uses only the portions of past,present,and future cash flows that are related to current accruals.Since we cannot identify these cashDechow and Dichev—The Quality of Accruals and Earnings 41TABLE 1Derivation of Sample,1987to 1999Firm-years with available cash from operations,earnings,and changes in accountsreceivable and inventory and total assets reported in the statement of cash flows59,360Firm-years after truncation of the most extreme 1percent of earnings,cash fromoperations,and changes in working capital55,850Firm-years with both lead and lag values of cash from operations30,317Firms with 8or more annual observations1,725Firm-years available for the 1,725firms used in the remaining analysis15,234Three-digit SIC groups with over 50observations136Firm-years available for the 136industries27,204All data is from Compustat.flow components,the empirical version in Expression (5)uses total CFOs.2Thus,the in-dependent variables in Expression (5)are measured with error,implying that the regression coefficients are likely to be biased toward 0,and the R 2will be reduced.Since the theoretical values of the coefficients from Equation (4)are b 1ϭ1,b 2ϭϪ1,and b 3ϭ1,we expect that 0Ͻb 1Ͻ1,and Ϫ1Ͻb 2Ͻ0,and 0Ͻb 3Ͻ1.Appendix B provides a more expansive treatment of this issue,including simulation results that confirm that the estimated coeffi-cients and the R 2will be biased toward zero.Appendix B also reveals that the bias is more severe for b 1and b 3as compared to b 2,because the error component in past and future cash flows is greater than the component in current cash flter in the paper (Section IV),we implement additional tests to control for the effect of this measurement error on our results.Finally,we add an intercept to Expression (5)to capture possible nonzero average accruals (e.g.,average positive working capital accruals due to firm growth).III.SAMPLE SELECTION,DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS,AND CALIBRATION TESTSTable 1summarizes our sample selection.Our sample is obtained from the Compustat annual industrial and research files over 1987to 1999.Given Collins and Hribar’s (2002)result that the balance-sheet approach to deriving CFO leads to noisy and biased estimates,we use CFO as given in the Statement of Cash Flows reported under the Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No.95(SFAS No.95,FASB 1987).3The sample is re-stricted to firms with complete data for assets,earnings,cash flow from operations,changes in accounts receivable,and changes in inventory.The last two requirements ensure sample firms have significant working capital accruals.Truncating the most extreme 1percent of cash from operations,earnings,and changes in working capital,and requiring at least one 2Property-casualty insurance firms provide information about their accrual estimates,the subsequent cash flow realizations,and the resulting estimation errors (e.g.,Petroni 1992;Anthony and Petroni 1997;Beaver and McNichols 1998).We do not pursue an industry-specific analysis because the cross-industry variation in the magnitude of estimation errors is likely to be larger than the typical within-industry variation,and because our interest is in more generalizable results.3This Standard required the presentation of the statement of cash flows for fiscal years ending after July 15,1988.However,some firms adopted this standard early in 1987.42The Accounting Review,2002Supplement year of past and future cash flows and earnings,yields a sample of 30,317firm-years.In addition,we require at least eight years of data to estimate firm-specific regressions.This restriction reduces our sample to 15,234firm-year observations for 1,725firms.4For some of our industry-level analyses,less stringent data requirements yield a sample of 27,204firm-year observations over 136three-digit SIC industries.Cash flow from operations is Compustat item 308.The change in working capital from year t Ϫ1to t (⌬WC),is computed as ⌬AR ϩ⌬Inventory Ϫ⌬AP Ϫ⌬TP ϩ⌬Other Assets (net),where AR is accounts receivable,AP is accounts payable,and TP is taxes payable.Specifically,⌬WC is calculated from Compustat items as ⌬WC ϭϪ(item 302ϩitem 303ϩitem 304ϩitem 305ϩitem 307).We calculate earnings after short-term accruals but before long-term accruals (Earn)as Earn ϭCFO ϩ⌬WC.We report Earnings before extraordinary items (Prof)as Compustat item 123,and Accruals (Prof-CFO)to provide comparability with other research.All var-iables are scaled by average total assets.We also calculate the length of the operating cycle (OC)as:360/(Sales/Average AR)ϩ360/(Cost of Goods Sold)/(Average Inventory)where Sales is Compustat item 12,cost of goods sold is item 41,AR is item 2,and Inventory is item 3.Descriptive statistics and correlations are provided in Table 2.An examination of Panel A reveals that descriptive statistics are in line with those of other studies using similar variables and time period (e.g.,Barth et al.2001).Earn exceeds CFO,implying that short-term accruals are mostly positive.This is not surprising,given that most firms are growing and therefore increasing their working capital.As expected,average accruals are negative (Ϫ0.046),primarily because of depreciation.The Pearson correlations in Panels B and C of Table 2illustrate the relations between our sample variables and provide comparability with previous research (results for Spear-man correlations are similar).These empirical correlations are in agreement with existing findings and the predictions of the model.Specifically,there is a positive contemporaneous correlation between Earn and CFO (0.73),and between Earn and ⌬WC (0.33),and a neg-ative correlation between CFO and ⌬WC (Ϫ0.41).We also find that Accruals and ⌬WC are highly positively correlated (0.75),suggesting that working capital accruals capture much of the variation in total accruals.Consistent with Barth et al.(2001),we find that earnings and changes in working capital anticipate future cash flows from operations.Note that the simple correlation between ⌬WC t and CFO t ϩ1is Ϫ0.01and statistically insignificant.As previously discussed,the reason is that ⌬WC t is negatively correlated with CFO t ,and CFO t is positively correlated with CFO t ϩ1(0.56),which counteracts the expected positive relation between ⌬WC t and CFO t ϩ1.In Panel C of Table 2,we report that the partial correlation between ⌬WC t and CFO t ϩ1,controlling for CFO t ,is 0.29(significant at the 0.0001level).We also find that working capital accruals are positively related to past cash flows,implying that accruals defer the recognition of some past cash flows.The simple correlation between ⌬WC t and CFO t Ϫ1in Panel B is only 0.008but the partial correlation controlling for CFO t in Panel C is 0.31(significant at the 0.0001level).Summarizing,our descriptive statistics and correlation results are in line with predictions and existing results,indicating that our model captures reasonably well some of the key features of accrual accounting.4481firms have eight available observations,1,054have nine observations,and 190firms have ten observations.Dechow and Dichev—The Quality of Accruals and Earnings43TABLE2Descriptive Statistics and Correlations for15,234Firm-Year Observations1987to1999Panel A:Descriptive StatisticsMean StandardDeviationLowerQuartile MedianUpperQuartileCashflow from operations(CFO)0.0750.0970.0330.0820.131 Change in working capital(⌬WC)0.0150.070Ϫ0.0150.0100.044 Earnings before long-term accruals(Earn)0.0910.0930.0570.0960.141 Earnings before extraordinary items(Prof)0.0300.1130.0090.0420.081 Accruals(Prof-CFO)Ϫ0.0460.098Ϫ0.084Ϫ0.044Ϫ.0035 Total Assets(in millions)2,43610,878502401,215 Panel B:Pearson CorrelationsEarnt CFOt⌬WC t CFO tϩ1CFO tϪ1Earn tϩ1Accruals tProft0.816*0.575*0.292*0.458*0.470*0.540*0.585*Earnt0.728*0.325*0.571*0.575*0.674*0.220*CFOtϪ0.411*0.558*0.549*0.597*Ϫ0.327*⌬WC tϪ0.0110.0080.072*0.745*CFOtϩ10.482*0.735*Ϫ0.024CFOtϪ10.491*Ϫ0.001Earntϩ10.031*Panel C:Partial Correlations(controlling for the effect of CFOt)PearsonCorrelation CFOtϩ1CFOtϪ1⌬WC t0.289*0.306**Significant at the0.0001level.Variable definitions:Cashflow from operations(CFO)ϭitem308from the Compustat Statement of Cash Flows;Change in working capital(⌬WC)ϭ⌬ARϩ⌬InventoryϪ⌬APϪ⌬TPϩ⌬Other Assets(net),where AR is accounts receivable,AP is accounts payable,andTP is taxes payable;Earnings before long-term accruals(Earn)ϭCFOϩ⌬WC;Earnings before extraordinary items(Prof)ϭCompustat item123;andAccrualsϭProfϪCFO.All variables are scaled by average total assets.IV.RESULTSAn Empirical Measure of Accrual QualityTable3presents results of regressions of working capital accruals on past,present,and future cashflows from operations.First,we presentfirm-level regressions(Panel A)because44The Accounting Review,2002SupplementTABLE3Regressions of the Change in Working Capital on Past,Current,and Future Cash Flow from Operations for Firm-Years between1987to1999⌬WC tϭb0ϩb1CFO tϪ1ϩb2CFO tϩb3CFO tϩ1ϩ␧tIntercept b1b2b3Adjusted R2Panel A:Firm-Specific Regressions(1,725firms)Mean0.040.17Ϫ0.620.090.47(t-statistic)(23.03)(19.38)(Ϫ57.06)(10.38)Lower quartile0.001Ϫ0.02Ϫ0.91Ϫ0.100.23 Median0.040.14Ϫ0.650.090.55 Upper quartile0.080.35Ϫ0.350.280.80 Panel B:Industry-Specific Regressions(136industries)Mean0.030.19Ϫ0.510.150.34 (t-statistic)(16.09)(21.10)(Ϫ35.77)(15.33)Lower quartile0.010.11Ϫ0.630.080.22 Median0.030.18Ϫ0.520.150.34 Upper quartile0.040.26Ϫ0.400.230.45 Panel C:Pooled Regression(15,234firm-year observations)Coefficient0.030.19Ϫ0.510.180.29 (t-statistic)(39.43)(32.12)(Ϫ78.29)(29.18)The t-statistics in Panel A are determined based on the distribution of the1,725coefficients obtained from the firm-specific regressions requiring a minimum of eight observations perfirm.T-statistics in Panel B are determined based on the distribution of the136coefficients obtained from three-digit SIC grouping regressions requiring a minimum of50observations per grouping.All variables are defined as in Table2.our theory is defined and most naturally applied on afirm-level basis.In addition,we expect that afirm-level specification is superior to cross-sectional specifications because the regression coefficients are likely to differ acrossfirms.The reason is that our operating cashflow proxies contain measurement error,which is likely to be systematically related tofirm characteristics.For example,a long operating cycle implies that substantial future cashflows are recognized in current earnings(e.g.,by accruing receivables).As a result, when future cashflows related to present accruals are a large part of total future cashflows, we expect that total future cashflows will load with a larger coefficient in Expression(5). Since such effects are likely related tofirm-level characteristics,we believe that afirm-level specification is superior.However,we also present industry-specific and pooled results (Panels B and C),because ourfirm-specific time-series is short,and we are concerned about noisy estimation at thefirm level.Results for thefirm-specific regressions in Panel A of Table3are consistent with the theory and the univariate results in Table2.As predicted,current changes in working capital。

企业营运资金管理中英文对照外文翻译文献

企业营运资金管理中英文对照外文翻译文献

中英文对照外文翻译文献(文档含英文原文和中文翻译)原文:Effects Of Working Capital Management On Sme ProfitabilityThe corporate finance literature has traditionally focused on the study of long-term financial decisions. Researchers have particularly offered studies analyzing investments, capital structure, dividends or company valuation, among other topics. But the investment that firms make in short-term assets, and the resources used with maturities of under one year, represent the main share of items on a firm’s balance sheet. In fact, in our sample the current assets of small and medium-sized Spanish firms represent 69.48 percent of their assets, and at the same time their current liabilities represent more than 52.82 percent of their liabilities.Working capital management is important because of its effects on the firm’s profitability and risk, and consequently its value (Smith, 1980). On the one hand, maintaining high inventory levels reduces the cost of possible interruptions in the production process, or of loss of business due to the scarcity of products, reducessupply costs, and protects against price fluctuations, among other advantages (Blinder and Manccini, 1991). On the other, granting trade credit favors the firm’s sales in various ways. Trade credit can act as an effective price cut (Brennan, Maksimovic and Zechner,1988; Petersen and Rajan, 1997), incentivizes customers to acquire merchandise at times of low demand (Emery, 1987), allows customers to check that the merchandise they receive is as agreed (quantity and quality) and to ensure that the services contracted are carried out (Smith, 1987), and helps firms to strengthen long-term relationships with their customers (Ng, Smith and Smith, 1999). However, firms that invest heavily in inventory and trade credit can suffer reduced profitability. Thus,the greater the investment in current assets, the lower the risk, but also the lower the profitability obtained.On the other hand, trade credit is a spontaneous source of financing that reduces the amount required to finance the sums tied up in the inventory and customer accounts. But we should bear in mind that financing from suppliers can have a very high implicit cost if early payment discounts are available. In fact the opportunity cost may exceed 20 percent, depending on the discount percentage and the discount period granted (Wilner,2000; Ng, Smith and Smith, 1999). In this respect, previous studies have analyzed the high cost of trade credit, and find that firms finance themselves with seller credit when they do not have other more economic sources of financing available (Petersen and Rajan, 1994 and 1997).Decisions about how much to invest in the customer and inventory accounts, and how much credit to accept from suppliers, are reflected in the firm’s cash conve rsion cycle, which represents the average number of days between the date when the firm must start paying its suppliers and the date when it begins to collect payments from its customers. Some previous studies have used this measure to analyze whether shortening the cash conversion cycle has positive or negative effects on the firm’s profitability.Specifically, Shin and Soenen (1998) analyze the relation between the cash conversion cycle and profitability for a sample of firms listed on the US stock exchange during the period 1974-1994. Their results show that reducing the cash conversion cycle to a reasonable extent increases firms’ profitability. More recently,Deloof (2003) analyzes a sample of large Belgian firms during the period 1992-1996. His results confirm that Belgian firms can improve their profitability by reducing the number of days accounts receivable are outstanding and reducing inventories. Moreover, he finds that less profitable firms wait longer to pay their bills.These previous studies have focused their analysis on larger firms. However, the management of current assets and liabilities is particularly important in the case of small and medium-sized companies. Most of these companies’ assets are in the form of current assets. Also, current liabilities are one of their main sources of external finance in view of their difficulties in obtaining funding in the long-term capital markets(Petersen and Rajan, 1997) and the financing constraints that they face (Whited, 1992; Fazzari and Petersen, 1993). In this respect, Elliehausen and Woken (1993), Petersen and Rajan (1997) and Danielson and Scott (2000) show that small and medium-sized US firms use vendor financing when they have run out of debt. Thus, efficient working capital management is particularly important for smaller companies (Peel and Wilson,1996).In this context, the objective of the current work is to provide empirical evidence about the effects of working capital management on profitability for a panel made up of 8,872 SMEs during the period 1996-2002. This work contributes to the literature in two ways. First, no previous such evidence exists for the case of SMEs. We use a sample of Spanish SMEs that operate within the so-called continental model, which is characterized by its less developed capital markets (La Porta, López-de-Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishny, 1997), and by the fact that most resources are channeled through financial intermediaries (Pampillón, 2000). All this suggests that Spanish SMEs have fewer alternative sources of external finance available, which makes them more dependent on short-term finance in general, and on trade credit in particular. As Demirguc-Kunt and Maksimovic (2002) suggest, firms operating in countries with more developed banking systems grant more trade credit to their customers, and at the same time they receive more finance from their own suppliers. The second contribution is that, unlike the previous studies by Shin and Soenen (1998) and Deloof (2003), in the current work we have conducted tests robust to the possible presence ofendogeneity problems. The aim is to ensure that the relationships found in the analysis carried out are due to the effects of the cash conversion cycle on corporate profitability and not vice versa.Our findings suggest that managers can create value by reducing their firm’s number of days accounts receivable and inventories. Similarly, shortening the cash conversion cycle also improves the firm’s profitability.We obtained the data used in this study from the AMADEUS database. This database was developed by Bureau van Dijk, and contains financial and economic data on European companies.The sample comprises small and medium-sized firms from Spain. The selection of SMEs was carried out according to the requirements established by the European Commission’s recommendation 96/280/CE of 3 April, 1996, on the definition of small and medium-sized firms. Specifically, we selected those firms meeting the following criteria for at least three years: a) have fewer than 250 employees; b) turn over less than €40 million; and c) possess less than €27 million of total assets.In addition to the application of those selection criteria, we applied a series of filters. Thus, we eliminated the observations of firms with anomalies in their accounts, such as negative values in their assets, current assets, fixed assets, liabilities, current liabilities, capital, depreciation, or interest paid. We removed observations of entry items from the balance sheet and profit and loss account exhibiting signs that were contrary to reasonable expectations. Finally, we eliminated 1 percent of the extreme values presented by several variables. As a result of applying these filters, we ended up with a sample of 38,464 observations.In order to introduce the effect of the economic cycle on the levels invested in working capital, we obtained information about the annual GDP growth in Spain from Eurostat.In order to analyze the effects of working capital management on the firm’s profitability, we used the return on assets (ROA) as the dependent variable. We defined this variable as the ratio of earnings before interest and tax to assets.With regards to the independent variables, we measured working capitalmanagement by using the number of days accounts receivable, number of days of inventory and number of days accounts payable. In this respect, number of days accounts receivable (AR) is calculated as 365 ×[accounts receivable/sales]. This variable represents the average number of days that the firm takes to collect payments from its customers. The higher the value, the higher its investment in accounts receivable.We calculated the number of days of inventory (INV) as 365 ×[inventories/purchases]. This variable reflects the average number of days of stock held by the firm. Longer storage times represent a greater investment in inventory for a particular level of operations.The number of days accounts payable (AP) reflects the average time it takes firms to pay their suppliers. We calculated this as 365 × [accounts payable/purchases]. The higher the value, the longer firms take to settle their payment commitments to their suppliers.Considering these three periods jointly, we estimated the cash conversion cycle(CCC). This variable is calculated as the number of days accounts receivable plus thenumber of days of inventory minus the number of days accounts payable. The longerthe cash conversion cycle, the greater the net investment in current assets, and hence the greater the need for financing of current assets.Together with these variables, we introduced as control variables the size of the firm, the growth in its sales, and its leverage. We measured the size (SIZE) as the logarithm of assets, the sales growth (SGROW) as (Sales1 –Sales0)/Sales0, the leverage(DEBT) as the ratio of debt to liabilities. Dellof (2003) in his study of large Belgian firms also considered the ratio of fixed financial assets to total assets as a control variable. For some firms in his study such assets are a significant part of total assets.However our study focuses on SMEs whose fixed financial assets are less important. In fact, companies in our sample invest little in fixed financial assets (a mean of 3.92 percent, but a median of 0.05 percent). Nevertheless, the results remain unaltered whenwe include this variable.Furthermore, and since good economic conditions tend to be reflected in a firm’sprofitability, we controlled for the evolution of the economic cycle using the variable GDPGR, which measures the annual GDP growth.Current assets and liabilities have a series of distinct characteristics according to the sector of activity in which the firm operates. Thus, Table I reports the return on assets and number of days accounts receivable, days of inventory, and days accounts payable by sector of activity. The mining industry and services sector are the two sectors with the highest return on their assets, with a value of 10 percent. Firms that are dedicated to agriculture, trade (wholesale or retail), transport and public services, are some way behind at 7 percent.With regard to the average periods by sector, we find, as we would expect, that the firms dedicated to the retail trade, with an average period of 38 days, take least time to collect payments from their customers. Construction sector firms grant their customers the longest period in which to pay –more than 145 days. Next, we find mining sector firms, with a number of days accounts receivable of 116 days. We also find that inventory is stored longest in agriculture, while stocks are stored least in the transport and public services sector. In relation to the number of days accounts payable, retailers (56 days) followed by wholesalers (77 days) pay their suppliers earliest. Firms are much slower in the construction and mining sectors, taking more than 140 days on average to pay their suppliers. However, as we have mentioned, these firms also grant their own customers the most time to pay them. Considering all the average periods together, we note that the cash conversion cycle is negative in only one sector – that of transport and public services. This is explained by the short storage times habitual in this sector. In this respect, agricultural and manufacturing firms take the longest time to generate cash (95 and 96 days, respectively), and hence need the most resources to finance their operational funding requirements.Table II offers descriptive statistics about the variables used for the sample as a whole. These are generally small firms, with mean assets of more than €6 milli on; their return on assets is around 8 percent; their number of days accounts receivable is around 96 days; and their number of days accounts payable is very similar: around 97 days. Together with this, the sample firms have seen their sales grow by almost 13percent annually on average, and 24.74 percent of their liabilities is taken up by debt. In the period analyzed (1996-2002) the GDP has grown at an average rate of 3.66 percent in Spain.Source: Pedro Juan García-Teruel and Pedro Martínez-Solano ,2006.“Effects of Working Capital Management on SME Profitability” .International Journal of Managerial Finance ,vol. 3, issue 2, April,pages 164-167.译文:营运资金管理对中小企业的盈利能力的影响公司理财著作历来把注意力集中在了长期财务决策研究,研究者详细的提供了投资决策分析、资本结构、股利分配或公司估值等主题的研究,但是企业投资形成的短期资产和以一年内到期方式使用的资源,表现为公司资产负债表的有关下昂目的主要部分。

Private firms

Private firms

Private firms etcdebt cash flow.If leverage is going to change significantly over time this is important. However FCFF does require we know debt ratios and interest rates for WACC.Firms with high leverage or changing leverage best to use FCFF.Volatility induced by debt payments has a high effect on equity value and is hard to Equity is more sensitive to assumptions about growth and risk than is the overallOften FCFE is negative this is a problem. Whereas FCFF is unlikely to be negative since interest payments have to be made! Debt also needs to either trade at fair price or be explicitly valued to calculate the equityIt is not uncommon in the situation ofrapidly changing debt ratios to use a value of equity plus interest shield onAssume company is all equity andAdd the interest shield on debt discounted at cost of debt for each Critical inputs are easier for public firms than private ones.Otherwise it is still a DCF or real option or whatever sophistication of the basicTake a number of different forms not just Less stringent accounting requirements.No historical prices –information gap as to Tend to be smaller.Ownership and management not separated.Tend to invest bulk of owner wealth in firm.Estimating discount rates Estimating cash flowsEstimating discount rates Problem of optimal debt ratios Market value of debtBorrow from banks not focused on ratings or spreads like public companies are Beta assumes diversifiedImplicit in beta is marginal investor is well -Is this true for private firms?Use of beta of comparable firm will underestimate the risk.Assume near term IPO or sell to Can use market beta.Add premium to cover inability to Adjust beta to measure total risk2Market Total =R ββEstimated from earnings rather than Regress earnings on aggregate earnings of Primary problem is that earnings aremeasured less frequently and subject to accounting measurement practices.How do these compare with return betas?Publicly traded firm betas areregressed against financial fundamentals such as earnings volatility dividend payout and leverage. This relationship is then applied to private companies to predict betas. Again the quality is dependent on the quality of the inputs!Expenses associated with management salary or perquisites have to be studied.If being taken IPO tax laws may change and effects can be significant.Private firms face additional expenses such as record keeping exchange costs etc once IPO.Past growth rates and other estimates create noise in estimation.Usually much higher if decision maker ispremium for diversifiable risk.The cash flows may be higher or lower depending on taxes and efficiencies of owner managers work.If cash flows small will reject projects public companies would have taken on (because of lower discount rate).If acquire a private firm one source of synergy is the removal or loosening of investment constraints under which private firm operates.The greater the constraints greaterAs cost of foregone projects increases more likely to attempt to go public.Can be greater as personal assets can be taken against defaultFewer assets to protect from indirect costs Less leeway in renegotiating debt Therefore less likely to borrow.Cannot be bought and sold as easily as publicly traded securities.Makes less attractive as investments. Therefore is the a liquidity discount.Types of assets owned by firm.Size of business.Health of business.Cash flow generating capacity.Approach 1: Based on past studies use average of 30% for private firms.Make subjective adjustments to this. Approach 2: Estimate discount rate as a function of size of firm, stability of CF, type of assets, cash flow generating Many businesses derive significant valueoften the owner. Provides a significant portion of the value Eg restaurants, delis, florists, brokers, investment advisors etc.Estimate effect of replacing with another Calculate the value of the business on basis of these new cash flows.In extreme cases value can drop to zero! Value firm NOT the equity!Usually happens because too much debt. If we value before debt cash flows canavoid problems of valuing equity which will have negative cash flows.Then take out debt and what is left is actual equity which shapes the shareAlternatively use average earnings based on a period when they were healthier thanAssuming will revert back!From distressed firm is when it is moving In US when it is in chapter 11.If you can identify this period make some Accuracy linked to assumptions about the probability of transition and the period of Discounted cash flows predicated on the going concern assumption.Liquidation value.Aggregate value that assets would command if sold at market prices net of costs. Value of equity is what is left afterDifficult if assets not easily separated.Likelihood that fetch market value usually slim in a fire sale scenario.Option pricing models.If value of assets < value of debt then useEquity can be viewed as an out of the money call on the underlying firm.Identify issues that fact off shore Language and cultureAgency theory is a branch of game theory that studies the design of contracts to motivate a rational agent to act on behalf of a principal when the agent s interests would otherwise conflict with those of the Basically the agent does not bear the full responsibility of actions alone.And the principal cannot observe in fullof the agent.Also different responses to outcomes. CEO and shareholdersEquity and Bond holdersShareholders and managers operate in different environments with differentLeisure preferences.Risk preferences.Time preferences.Likewise, equity and bond holders have different preferences, cash flow expectations and outcomes.Cannot observe effort so link payment to some observable measure that is positively correlated with effort.One thing observable is gross profits p. Gets a wage wl when profits are low pl. Gets wh when profits are high ph.Difference is the risk premium to compensate the manger.What if profits under shirking are greater than under hard work?Ie inducing hard work is too costly.Managers need to have discretion inThis allows for self interest. Cannot fully observe activities.However results and behaviour not perfectly correlated.Performance pay schemes so common would think they are good.What are some of the problems?Incentive pay schemes place more risk on the manager as it fluctuates with the firm.Benchmarking to accounting profits.If only some tasks are rewarded and others not will neglect the other tasks.E.G. Sales volume drives bonus of brokers. Increasing revenues.Team work not rewarded why work in aHold down performance in observation period to look good in the next period.Timing of targets if intervals too short leads to short term goal setting.Managers want a good reputation in the The repeat game theory.The traditional theories do not seem to hold in the experimental setting.Rather reputation effects are very You are an equity holder and can invest in one of two projects both have an expected NPV of $100M. Costs are $90M The firm is financed in part with debt and debt holders supply $80M in total inThey require regular payments of 10%.This is why there are covenants placed on firms by debt holders.。

英汉《商务管理沟通》常用词汇()

英汉《商务管理沟通》常用词汇()

Aabstract or executive summary 摘要或结语acknowledgment response 感知性反应action close (鼓励)行动性结尾active listening 积极地倾听active verb 主动式的动词adjustment 调整alliteration 头韵allness 误以为全面alternating pattern 交替方式AMS Simplified format 行政管理协会简化式格式analytical report 分析性报告annual report 年度报告argument 论点assumption 假设Bbar graph 条状图behavioral interviews行为式面试bias-free language 非歧视性语言bibliography 参考书目blind ads (没有公司名称的)盲目广告blind copies 盲目(抄送)副本blindering 丧失方向性block format 齐头式blocking 阻碍body language 身体语言body 主体;正文boilerplate 引用boxhead 表头栏brainstorming 头脑风暴法branching question 分叉式问题bridge 过渡buffer 委婉语building goodwill 树立良好的信誉bullets 工程符号或编号business slang 商业俚语businessese 商业行话buying time with limited agreement 在有限制协议下的购买时间bypassing 旁路;错误传达Ccable TV 有线电视Cadillac 凯迪拉克Campbell's Soup 金宝汤业公司capital gains 资本收益capital invested in product 产品投入资本Carnival 嘉年华cash cows 现金牛类cash discounts 现金折扣catalogue sales 目录销售categorization of perception 感知分类categorization 分门别类Caterpillar Tractor 卡特皮勒公司Cathay Airlines 国泰航空公司CBS Records 唱片公司CBS 哥伦比亚广播公司centralization 集中化chameleons/followers 变色龙/跟随者channel alternatives 可选择的营销渠道channel conflicts 渠道冲突channel decisions 渠道决策channel functions 渠道功能channel institutions 渠道组织结构channel management 渠道管理channel objectives 渠道目标channel of distribution 分销渠道channel power 渠道权力channel-control strategies 渠道控制战略channel-design decisions 渠道设计决策channel-management decisions 渠道管理决策channels of communication 传播渠道Charles Snow 查尔斯·斯诺Cherokee 切诺基chevrolet 雪佛莱choice criteria 选择标准Christian Dior 克里斯汀·迪奥(世界著名时装品牌)Chrysler 克莱斯勒Citi Corp 花旗银行closing a sale 结束销售clothing retailers 服装零售商CNN 美国有线新闻网co-branding 联合品牌code of ethics (职业)道德标准coercive power 强制权cognitive dissonance 认识的不协调Colgate-Palmolive 高露洁collection of data 数据收集collection 收款co-marketing alliances 联合营销联盟combination compensation plan 结合式薪酬方案Comdex 计算机展销会commercialization 商业化commitment 承诺communication channels 传播渠道communication process 传播过程communication 信息交流/沟通communications media 传播媒体company personnel 公司员工Compaq 康柏comparative advertisements 比较广告comparison of brands 品牌比较compensation deals 补偿处理compensation plan 酬金方案compensation/rewards 酬金/奖励compensatory 补偿性的competition and industry evolution 竞争和行业演变competition-orientated pricing 竞争导向定价法competitive advantage 竞争优势competitive (supply-side) evolution 竞争(供方)演变competitive factors 竞争因素competitive intelligence 竞争情报/信息competitive parity promotion budgeting 竞争均势促销预算法competitive strategy 竞争战略competitive strength 竞争优势/能力competitor analysis 竞争者分析complaint handling 投诉处理component materials and parts markets 组成材料和零部件市场computerized ordering 计算机化的订购conclusive research 确定性研究conditions of demand 需求情况conflict and resolution strategies 冲突和解决战略conformance to specifications 与规格一致conformance 一致性confrontation strategy 对抗战略conjoint measurement 联合测度法conjunctive model 联合模型consumer decision-making 消费者(购买)决策consumer goods channels 消费品分销渠道Consumer Goods Pricing Act, USA 美国消费品定价法案consumer goods 消费品consumer markets 消费品市场consumer needs 消费者需求consumer packaged-goods firms 消费者包装食品公司consumer promotion 消费者促销consumer tests 消费者测试consumer/household market 消费者/家庭市场consumers' perceptions 消费者感知consumption 消费contests 竞赛contingency planning 权变计划contract construction 契约建筑业contract manufacturing 契约制造业contraction/strategic withdrawal strategy 收缩/战略性撤退战略contractual entry modes 契约式进入模式contractual vertical marketing systems 合约式垂直营销系统contribution margin analysis 边际贡献(贡献毛利)分析contributrion margin 边际贡献control strategies 控制战略convenience food stores 便利食品商店convenience goods 便利品convenience 服务的便利性Cool Whip 清凉维普co-operative advertising 合作性广告co-ordination and conflict resolution 协调与冲突解决co-production 合作生产core benefit proposition (CBP) 核心利益方案/提议corollary-data method 推定数据法corporate HQ 公司总部corporate scope 公司(经营)范围corporate strategy 公司战略corporate vertical marketing systems 公司式垂直营销系统corporate/institutional advertising 团体/社会公共机构广告corrective action 矫正行动cost analysis 成本分析cost effectiveness 成本有效性cost leadership strategy 成本领先战略cost of capital 资本成本cost of goods sold (COGS) 产品销售成本cost reductions 降低成本产品cost-and-volume relationship 成本-数量关系cost-oriented pricing 成本导向定价法cost-plus/mark-up pricing 成本加成/溢价定价法costs and benefits of marketing functions 营销职能的成本和效益costs of competitors 竞争者成本costs of distribution 分销成本countertrade 对等贸易coupons 优惠券courtesy 礼貌coverage of geographic market 地域性市场的范围coverage of relevant retailers 相关零售商的销售范围credibility 信誉credit terms 信贷条款critical assumptions 关键假设cross-elasticity 交叉弹性customary pricing 习惯性定价法customer analysis 顾客分析customer contact 顾客接触customer demand 顾客需求customer intimacy 顾客亲密度customer loyalty 顾客忠诚度customer need 顾客需要customer organization of sales force 按客户组织销售队伍customer retention 顾客维系/保留customer satisfaction 顾客满意度customer segment pricing 顾客细分市场定价customer service 顾客服务customer-oriented pricing 顾客导向定价法customers' perception 顾客感知customers' preferences 顾客偏好customers' price sensitivity 顾客的价格敏感度customizing 定制Ddata collection 数据收集data confidentiality 数据保密data research 数据研究data sources 数据来源dealers 经销商deceptive advertisements 欺骗性广告deciders 决策者declining markets 衰退市场decoding 解码defect rate 缺陷率defender strategy 防御型战略defensive new-product development strategy 防御性新产品开发战略defensive positioning 防御性定位delivery time 交付时间delivery 配送Dell Computers 戴尔计算机公司Delta Airlines 三角洲航空公司demand characteristics 需求特征demand curve 需求曲线demand-oriented pricing 需求导向定价法demographic environment 人口统计环境department stores 百货商店dependability 可靠性deregulation 放松管制derived demand 衍生需求descriptive research 描述性研究design decisions 设计决策desired percentage mark-up on retail 预期零售利润率desired percentage return 预期回报率determinant attributes 关键属性determinants 决定因素different responses 差别反应differentiated defender strategy 差异化防御战略differentiated marketing 差异化营销differentiation over time 不同时间的差异differentiation strategy 差异化战略differentiation 差异化diffusion of innovation theory 创新扩散理论dimension 因素dimensions of quality 质量维度direct costing profitability analysis 直接成本盈利性分析direct mail 直接邮寄direct marketing via advertising media 通过广告媒体的直接营销direct marketing 直接营销direct product profitability (DPP) 直接产品盈利性/利润率direct selling 直销discount rate 贴现率discount stores 折扣商店discount 折扣discount/premium price policies 折扣/溢价策略discriminant analysis 差异分析法discriminatory adjustments 歧视价格调整discriminatory pricing adjustments 歧视定价调整disjunctive model 分离模型display space 陈列空间disposable income 可支配收入dissonance-attribution hierarchy 不和谐-归属层次结构distribution channel designs 分销渠道设计distribution channel objectives 分销渠道的目标distribution channel 分销渠道distribution decisions 分销决策distribution policies 分销策略distribution 分销distributor/store (private lables) brands 分销商/私有品牌distributors 分销商diversification 多元化divest 撤退divest 出让divestment or liquidation 收回投资或清算dividend 红利dogs 瘦狗类domestic target marketing strategies 国内目标市场定位的营销战略dropping products 放弃产品dry cleaning 干洗dual/two channel distribution systems 双重分销系统duplication (媒体)重复DuPont 杜邦公司durability 耐用性Eearly vs late adoption 早期采购与后期采购earnings per share 每股收益economic and technological factors 经济技术因素economic power 经济权economies of scale 规模经济education services 教育服务effectiveness 有效性efficiency 效率Electrolux 伊莱克斯emergency goods 急需品Emerson Electric 爱默生电气emotional appeals 情感诉求empathy 移情作用empirical evidence 经验性实例empowerment 授权encoding 编码end use 最终使用endorsement 赞同engineering (产品)工程设计entrepreneurial strategy 企业家战略entry strategies 进入战略environment and packaging disposal 环境与包装处理environment factors 环境因素environmental scanning 环境扫描/分析environmental strategy 环境战略establishment 机构ethical audit (公司)伦理审计ethics of marketing 营销伦理道德ethnic composition 种族构成European Community 欧共体evaluation and reward systems 评估与奖励体系evaluation and selection of supplier 评估和选择供应商evaluation of alternatives 评估替代品/各种选择evaluation of brands 品牌评估event sponsorship 事件赞助event 活动everyday low-price (EDLP) 天天低价evoked set 引发的组合evolution of market 市场演变exchange 交换exclusive dealing 独家销售exclusive distribution 独家分销executive summary 执行摘要exhibition media 展示广告媒体existing market 现有市场exit barriers 退出壁垒expansion path 扩张途径expectation measures (顾客)预期测度expectations of customers 顾客期望expected unit sales 预计产量expected value 期望价值experience curve 经验曲线experimental research 实验性研究expert power 专长权exploratory research 探索性研究export agents 出口代理(商)export jobbers 出口批发商export management company 出口管理公司export merchants 出口贸易商export 出口exporting 出口商品extended use strategy 扩大使用战略extending volume growth 扩大市场份额external data sources 外部数据来源external environment 外部环境extrapolation of past sales trends 过去销售趋势推测法Ffacilitating agencies 辅助/中介机构factor analysis 因素分析法fads 时尚family branding 家族品牌family life cycle 家庭生命周期family structure 家庭结构farm products 农产品fast-moving consumer goods (FMCG) 快速变动的消费品fear appeals 恐惧/顾虑诉求features 特征Federal Department Stores 联邦百货商店Federal Trade Code (FTC) 联邦贸易法案FedEx (Federal Express) 联邦快递feedback data 反馈数据field test marketing 实地市场测试financing 融资fisheries 渔业fit and finish 结实度与外观fixed costs 固定成本fixed salary 固定工资flanker strategy 侧翼进攻战略flanker/fighting brand 战斗品牌flanking and encirclement strategies 侧翼进攻与围堵战略flat organizational structure 扁平的组织结构FOB origin pricing FOB产地定价法focus strategy 集中战略followers 追随者Ford 福特公司foreign middlemen 国外中间商forestry 林业formalization 形式/规范化formulate 制定fortress/position-defence strategy 防御堡垒战略Fortune 《财富》杂志forward integration 向前一体化franchise systems 特许系统franchising 特许经营free call numbers 免费电话号码free goods 免费商品freight-absorption pricing 免收运费定价法fringe benefits 小额津贴frontal attack strategy 正面进攻战略full costing profitability analysis 全成本盈利性分析full-service wholesalers 全方位服务的批发商functional competencies and resource allocation 职能能力与资源分配functional efficiency 职能效率functional organization of sales force 按销售职能组织销售队伍functional organizational structure 职能型组织结构functional performance 功能性能functional strategy 职能战略Ggames 比赛gap 差距gatekeepers 信息传递者general behavioral descriptors 一般行为变量General Electric (GE) 通用电气General Foods Corporation 通用食品general merchandise discount chains 大众商品折扣连锁店General Motors 通用汽车geodemographics 区域人口统计特征geographic adjustments 地理调整geographic distribution 地理分布geographical organization of sales force 按地区组织销售队伍Gillette 吉列剔须刀global adjustments 全球调整global elite consumer segment 全球精英消费品市场global expansion 全球扩张global marketing control 全球营销控制global markets 全球市场global niche strategy 全球机会战略global standardization strategy 全球标准化战略global teenage segment 全球青少年市场globalization 全球化global-market expansion 全球市场扩张goals 总目标going-rate/competitive parity pricing 竞争性平价定价法goods producers 产品制造商Goodyear 固特异轮胎government agencies 政府机构government buyers 政府采购者government market 政府市场government regulation 政府管制greenhouse effect 温室效应grey market 灰色市场gross domestic product (GDP) 国内生产总值gross margin 毛利gross national product (GNP) 国民生产总值gross profit 毛利gross rating points (GRPs) 总级别指数group/category product manager 类别产品经理growing markets 成长市场growth rate of market 市场增长率growth stage of product life cycle 产品生命周期的成长阶段growth-extension strategies 增长扩张战略growth-market strategies for market leaders 市场领导者的市场增长战略growth-market strategy 成长性市场战略growth-market targeting strategy 成长性市场定位战略guarantee/warranty 保证/担保guarantees 保证Gucci 古琦(世界著名时装品牌)HHaagen-Dazs 哈根达斯hard technology 硬技术Harvard Business Review 《哈佛商业评论》harvest 收获harvesting pricing 收获定价法harvesting strategy 收获战略health care 医疗保健health maintenance organizations (HMOs) (美国)卫生保健组织heavy buyer 大客户Heileman Brewing CompanyHeinz 亨氏食品helpfulness 有益性Henkel 汉高Hertz 赫兹(美国汽车租赁巨头)Hewlett-Packard 惠普公司hierarchy of strategy 战略的层次high margin/low-turnover retailers 高利润/低周转率的零售商high market share global strategy 高市场份额全球战略high-contact service system 高接触服务系统high-involvement product 高参与产品high-involvement purchase 高参与购买hight market share 高市场份额战略Hilton 希尔顿Holiday Inns 假日旅馆homogeneous market 同质市场Honda 本田household/family life cycle 家庭生命周期household 家庭hybrid technology 混合技术IIBM 国际商用机器idea generation 创意的产生/生成ideas for new products 新产品创意/构想idea-screening process 创意筛选过程identification of segments 识别细分市场Illinois Tool Works 伊利诺斯工具厂image pricing 形象定价imitative positioning 模仿定位imitative strategy 模仿战略impact evaluation 影响评估impersonal sources 非个人的信息来源implementation and control of marketing programs 营销计划的执行和控制implementation 实施improvements in or revisions of existing products 现有产品的改良或修正impulse buying 冲动购买impulse goods 冲动购买品incentives 激励income 收入increased penetration strategy 增加渗透战略indirect costing profitability analysis 间接成本盈利性分析individual brand 个别品牌individual value 个人价值industrial goods & services 工业产品和服务industrial goods channels 工业品分销渠道industry attractiveness 行业吸引力industry attractiveness-business position matrix 行业吸引力-业务地位矩阵industry dynamics 产业动态industry evaluation 产业评估industry evolution 产业演变inelastic 缺乏价格弹性influencers 影响者infocommunications industry 信息通信行业infomercials 商业信息广告information age 信息时代information search 信息搜集information technology 信息技术information 信息informative 告知性的ingredient 成份in-home personal interview 个人家庭访谈in-house use tests 内部使用测试innovation 创新innovativeness 创新性installation 设施in-store display 店内展示in-store positioning 店内布局in-store promotion 店内促销intangibles 无形integrated marketing communication plan (IMC) 整合营销传播计划integration of perception 感知整合integration 整合Intel 因特尔intensity of market position 市场地位的集中程度intensity 集中程度intensive distribution 密集型分销interactions across multiple target markets 多目标市场间的相互作用interactive media 交互式媒体interest rates 利率internal data sources 内部数据来源internal marketing 内部营销internal organizational structure 内部组织结构international advertising 国际广告international channels 国际分销渠道international division 国际分部international marketing 国际营销international organizational design 国际组织设计internationalization of services 服务的国际化introductory stage of product life cycle 产品生命周期的推出阶段inventory level 库存水平investor relations advertising 投资关系广告issue advertising 观点广告。

Understanding earnings quality

Understanding earnings quality
Accruals : accruals means lower persistence. Accrual adjustments reduce the persistence of earnings Measurement problems : a contributing factor to the lower earnings persistence. Abnormal accounts receivable: conflicting results, still need research to reconcile the evidence. Inventory accruals : firms with indicators of poor quality inventory accruals have positive future changes in EPS and contemporaneous returns.
2. Commentary on the state of the literature
• Reported Earnings ≡ f (X) • X = enterprise’s financial performance during a reporting period • f = the accounting system that converts the unobservable X into observable earnings. • Discussion: Performance & Measurement of performance
(2) Abnormal accruals and modeling the accrual process • Accruals models:

Earnings Quality Based on Corporate Investment Decisions

Earnings Quality Based on Corporate Investment Decisions

DOI:10.1111/j.1475-679X.2010.00397.xJournal of Accounting ResearchVol.49No.3June2011Printed in U.S.A.Earnings Quality Basedon Corporate Investment DecisionsF E NG L I∗Received25July2007;accepted20September2010ABSTRACTIn this paper,I examine a new approach for measuring earnings quality,de-fined as the closeness of reported earnings to“permanent earnings,”based on firm decisions with regard to capital and labor investments.Specifically,I mea-sure earnings quality as the contemporaneous association between changes in the levels of capital and labor investment and the change in reported earnings.This approach follows the reasoning that(1)firms make invest-ment decisions based on the net present value(NPV)of investment projects and(2)reported earnings with higher quality should more closely associate with real investment decisions.Ifind that measures of earnings quality based on managerial labor and capital decisions correlate positively with earnings persistence and have incremental explanatory power relative to earnings-quality measures used in the accounting literature.Furthermore,investment-based earnings-quality measures are less informative when managers tend to overinvest.1.IntroductionPrior research on earnings quality generally relies on one of two ap-proaches:studying the properties of accounting numbers or extracting∗Stephen M.Ross School of Business,University of Michigan.I thank Ray Ball,Phil Berger, Ilia Dichev,Kenneth Merkley,workshop participants at the University of Chicago,and espe-cially an anonymous reviewer and Richard Leftwich(the journal editor)for their comments.721Copyright C ,University of Chicago on behalf of the Accounting Research Center,2011722F.LIinformation from stock prices.1This paper explores a new measure of earn-ings quality by examiningfirm investment decisions.2Managerial invest-ment decisions likely contain information about earnings quality because managers make many decisions based on future profitability,and arguably have more precise and complete information about theirfirm’s profitability than do other stakeholders.Therefore,to the extent that information asym-metry exists between managers and outsiders,the earnings quality inferred from managerial decisions can provide incremental information to existing empirical measures based on the information set of outside investors or on the properties of the accounting numbers.3In this study,I examine whether corporate investment decisions contain information about earnings quality.In a simplified setting,managers in-vest more in projects with a higher net present value(NPV).All else be-ing equal,if afirm’s expected future earnings or permanent earnings in-crease,then it makes additional investment,because permanent earnings are equivalent to annuitized NPV(Black[1980],Beaver[1998],Ohlson and Zhang[1998]).Hence,if afirm experiences an increase in reported earnings and management views this earnings innovation to be permanent (i.e.,the reported earnings have high“quality”),then thatfirm usually in-creases its investment level.However,if the innovation in reported earnings is purely transitory,then there should not be a corresponding change in the investment level.This reasoning suggests that earnings surprises that are more associated with changes in corporate investment decisions are more likely to be permanent and of higher quality than are earnings surprises that are less associated with such changes.Inferring earnings quality from corporate investment decisions has lim-itations.Because of agency problems,managers have incentives to over-invest for empire building and other reasons(Stein[2003]).As a result, project profitability does not solely determine observed investment deci-sions and this reduces these decisions’informativeness for assessing earn-ings quality.Ultimately,whether one can derive useful and reliable mea-sures of earnings quality from management investment decisions is an empirical question.In this paper,I provide empirical evidence to answer this question by first examining whether corporate investment-based earnings-quality mea-sures are informative about future earnings.I measure earnings quality by examining decisions regarding capital and labor investments,two of the 1See,for instance,Sloan[1996],Dechow and Dichev[2002],Francis,LaFond,Olsson, and Schipper[2005],Basu[1997],Collins,Maydew,and Weiss[1999],Francis and Schipper [1999],and Ecker,Francis,Kim,Olsson,and Schipper[2006].2I define earnings quality as the closeness of reported earnings to the“permanent earn-ings”following Dechow and Schrand[2004]and use earnings persistence to operationalize this concept.3Consistent with this argument,prior papersfind that managerial decisions,which include dividend policy(Skinner and Soltes[2009])and disclosure quality(Li[2008]),contain infor-mation about earnings quality.EARNINGS QUALITY AND CORPORATE INVESTMENT723 most important investment decisions managers make.I construct earnings-quality measures by regressing changes in the number of employees and the amounts of capital and R&D expenditures on the change in reported earnings,using rolling data from the last10years for everyfirm year.The slopes from these regressions capture the sensitivity of investment to the innovation in reported earnings and measure the information content of those earnings for expected future profitability as reflected in corporate in-vestment decisions.Because this regression approach requires a long time series of data,I also construct two other earnings-quality measures calcu-lated as the current changes in capital investment and labor investment(as proxied by the number of employees)divided by the change in reported earnings for everyfirm year.The empiricalfindings can be summarized as follows.First,the earnings-quality measures based on corporate investment decisions do not correlate highly with other commonly used measures of earnings quality.Thisfinding suggests that the information contained in corporate investment decisions differs somewhat from that reflected by stock prices and the properties of historical accounting numbers.I then show that earnings-quality measures based on corporate investment decisions positively associate with earnings persistence.Furthermore,the predictive power of investment-based earn-ings quality for earnings persistence still holds and is economically mean-ingful even after controlling for typical measures of earnings quality such as the absolute amount of accruals(Sloan[1996]),estimation errors in accruals(Dechow and Dichev[2002]),the earnings–returns association, and the volatility of earnings and accruals.I alsofind that the investment-based earnings quality contains significant information about future earn-ings only forfirms with a relatively low tendency to overinvest,measured us-ing the amount of free cashflows,the sensitivity of investment to cashflows, and the amount of excess investment based on Richardson[2006].Finally,I find that the investment decisions are more informative about future earn-ings for capital-intensivefirms,firms from highly unionized industries,and firms with a high frequency of earnings increases.These additional tests further validate the utility of corporate investment decisions for assessing earnings quality.Overall,the evidence indicates that there is substantial information in corporate investment decisions about earnings quality and it is incremental to other commonly used earnings-quality measures.However,researchers or investors need to consider the severity of possible overinvestment due to agency problems when using the investment-based earnings-quality mea-sures.The remainder of this paper is organized as follows.Section2discusses the literature on earnings quality and defines earnings-quality measures based on corporate investment decisions.Section3presents the data,sum-mary statistics of the measures,and their relation withfirm characteristics and other earnings-quality measures used in the literature.Section4pro-vides a discussion of the empirical results,and section5concludes.724F.LI2.Literature and Hypotheses Development2.1LITERATURE ON EARNINGS QUALITYThere is an extensive literature on the earnings quality(see Dechow and Schrand[2004]for a comprehensive review).However,because of its context-dependent nature,there is no consensus on the underlying con-ceptual construct that“earnings quality”represents.In this paper,I follow Dechow and Schrand[2004]and define earnings quality as the closeness of reported earnings to the“permanent earnings”(Black[1980],Beaver [1998],and Ohlson and Zhang[1998]).I use earnings persistence to oper-ationalize this concept.Earnings quality varies with many factors,including afirm’s business model and economic situation,estimation errors(Dechow and Dichev [2002]),and earnings management(Healy and Wahlen[1999]).To cap-ture earnings quality,prior studies generally follow one of two approaches. Thefirst approach measures earnings quality by using properties of the ob-served accounting numbers.The measures based on this approach include the level of accruals(Sloan[1996]),the estimation error in accruals(De-chow and Dichev[2002]),and the volatility of earnings(Dichev and Tang [2009]).Because of the historical nature of the current accounting system, the information contained in accounting numbers is unlikely to be com-plete concerning future profitability.The second approach focuses on the association between earnings and stock returns(e.g.,Basu[1997],Collins, Maydew,and Weiss[1999],Francis and Schipper[1999],and Ecker,Fran-cis,and Kim[2006]).This approach assumes market efficiency and extracts information about future earnings from stock prices.I take a different approach by emphasizing the management perspective. Managers arguably have more complete information about earnings qual-ity than do outsiders.Therefore,earnings-quality measures based on the information set of managers can provide better proxies for earnings qual-ity than measures that are based on historical accounting numbers or on the information set of outside equity investors.2.2EARNINGS QUALITY BASED ON FIRM INVESTMENT DECISIONSIn a simplified setting,making corporate investment decisions is straight-forward:afirm invests more if the marginal NPV of the investment project is positive.In accounting terms,the NPV of future investment is a mono-tonic function of the expected“permanent earnings,”which is essentially the annuitized NPV(Black[1980],Beaver[1998],and Ohlson and Zhang [1998]).Therefore,afirm invests(disinvests)if its permanent earnings increase(decrease).Ignoring potential agency problems,the association betweenfirms’observed investment decisions and reported earnings cap-tures the closeness of the reported earnings to the permanent earnings. Hence,the investment-earnings association provides information on the quality of the reported earnings.To the extent that managers have private information that investors do not have,corporate investment decisions canEARNINGS QUALITY AND CORPORATE INVESTMENT725 provide informative signals about earnings quality relative to the market-based earnings-quality measures.One point worth discussing is the parallel between afirm’s investment decision and the valuation of its equity by outside investors.In both cases, the involved parties(managers or investors)want to make their decisions by doing valuations based on the expected profitability of thefirm.Measuring earnings quality by using stock price information requires a maintained as-sumption of stock market efficiency,but assessing earnings quality through managerial investment decisions relies on the assumption that managers make optimal investment decisions.I seek to contribute to the literature that explores the implications of managerial decisions for earnings quality.Skinner and Soltes[2009]study the information content of dividend decisions byfirms for earnings qual-ity.Investment and dividend policies are both important managerial deci-sions and are likely to contain information about future -pared with dividend policy,firm labor and capital-investment decisions are simpler in the sense that they are less likely to be influenced by signaling considerations.A subtle difference between this paper and Skinner and Soltes[2009]is that their emphasis is on testing the dividend informa-tion content hypothesis,which has been examined in the dividend liter-ature and has not received much support.The purpose of this paper is to test whether corporate investment decisions,despite potential agency prob-lems,can provide information about earnings quality that is incremental to other typical earnings-quality constructs.Consequently,it is important to control for other measures of earnings quality.Empirically,I examine two types of investment decisions and their asso-ciations with reported earnings:labor and capital bor and capital are the two major factors that determine the output of afirm and they are also the main managerial decision parameters in microeconomics. The labor-and capital-investment decisions can be affected by different eco-nomic factors.Therefore,examining both decisions can complement each other.2.3OVERINVESTMENT AND INVESTMENT-BASED EARNINGS QUALITYIn this subsection,I explore the implications offirms’nonoptimal invest-ment decision making for the investment-based earnings quality.My moti-vation is the existence of agency problems,a central theme in the corporate finance literature with a lineage going back to Berle and Means[1932]and Jensen and Meckling[1976].Agency problems can lead to overinvestment by managers(Stein[2003]provides a comprehensive review of the litera-ture).One consequence of the agency problem is that managers have an excessive taste for running largefirms,as opposed to simply profitable ones. This“empire building”tendency is emphasized by Williamson[1964],Don-aldson[1984],and Jensen[1986],among many other studies.Agency problems can also give rise to overinvestment through channels other than“empire building.”Bertrand and Mullainathan[2003]argue that a managerial preference for the“quiet life”—effectively,a resistance to726F.LIchange—can lead to excessive continuation of negative-NPV projects.In a somewhat similar vein,Baker[2000]builds a model in which reputa-tional concerns deter managers from discontinuing negative-NPV projects, because this would be an admission of failure.Many empirical studies provide evidence on corporate overinvestment, including evidence from specific industries(e.g.,the oil industry overin-vestment documented by Jensen[1986])and evidence of poor acquisitions (Blanchard,de Silanes,and Shleifer[1994]).More recently,Richardson [2006]finds that investment decisions byfirms are excessively sensitive to current cashflows,which is a symptom of overinvestment.Ceteris paribus,if afirm is more likely to overinvest,its labor-and capital-investment decisions are less likely to be a useful signal of earnings quality because the investment decisions can be affected by other considerations (e.g.,empire building motivations)and are not solely determined by the profitability of the project.I therefore examine whether the information content of the investment-based earnings-quality measures varies with the overinvestment tendency cross-sectionally.I use three empirical constructs to measure the overinvestment ten-dency.First,Richardson[2006]shows thatfirms with a large amount of free cashflows tend to overinvest.Thisfinding implies that investment-based earnings-quality measures are less informative forfirms with more free cashflows.Second,a high sensitivity of investment to the free cash flows available for investment can indicate potential agency problems (Stein[2003]).4Richardson[2006]alsofinds thatfirms that tend to overinvest have higher investment–cashflow sensitivity.Hence,I use the investment–cashflow sensitivity as the second measure of the overinvest-ment tendency.Third,I rely directly on the overinvestment measure con-structed by Richardson[2006]for the cross-sectional tests.Because this measure directly relates to capital expenditure,I focus on the capital investment-based earnings-quality measures.To summarize,I expect that forfirms that are likely to overinvest(i.e.,firms that have more free cashflows,higher sensitivity of investment to cashflows,and more excess investment),the investment-based measures of earnings quality less strongly associate with earnings persistence and are less useful in predicting future earnings.3.Estimation of Earnings Quality Based on Investment Decisions3.1EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION OF EARNINGS QUALITYI obtain my sample from the Compustat annual industrial and research files between1952and2004.For everyfirm i in year T,I estimate the 4The corporatefinance literature also argues thatfirms with higher investment–cashflow sensitivity tend to have more severefinancing constraints,in addition to overinvestment prob-lems.Nevertheless,thefinancial constraint interpretation of the investment–cashflow sensi-tivity also leads to a prediction of suboptimal investment forfirms with higher investment–cash flow sensitivity.EARNINGS QUALITY AND CORPORATE INVESTMENT727 following two regressions using the data from year T−9to T: (NEMP i,t−NEMP i,t−1)/TA i,t−1=αL,iT+βL,iT(E i,t−E i,t−1)/TA i,t−1+ L,it(1) and(CAPX i,t+RND i,t−CAPX i,t−1−RND i,t−1)/TA i,t−1=αC,iT+βC,iT(E i,t−E i,t−1)/TA i,t−1+ C,it,(2) where T−9≤t≤T,NEMP is the number of employees at the end of afis-cal year(#29of the Compustat annualfiles),CAPX is the amount of capital expenditure for the year(#128),RND is the amount of R&D expenditure for the year(#46),E is the operating earnings(#178)with some possible adjustment(details in the next paragraph),and TA is the book value of assets at the end of thefiscal year(#6).Similar to prior studies(e.g.,Richardson[2006]),I include R&D expen-diture in the capital investment together with capital expenditure.My mo-tivation is the fact that,even though R&D is fully expensed under current U.S.generally accepted accounting principles(U.S.GAAP),prior studies show that the market views it more like an investment(Lev and Sougiannis [1996]).There is also a potential endogeneity problem in the estimation procedure—an increase in capital and R&D expenditures in a given year reduces the reported earnings because of additional expensing.This reduc-tion leads to a mechanical negative relation between investment and earn-ings.To mitigate this problem,I adjust the reported earnings by adding back the current R&D expense and the depreciation expense due to the new capital expenditure.Specifically,forfirm i in year t,E it is calculated asE it=#178+RND it+CAPX it/(PPE it/DEP it),(3) where PPE is the average of the beginning and end values of the gross amount of property,plant,and equipment(#7)and DEP is the depreci-ation expense(#14).This adjustment assumes that the new assets,due to current capital expenditure,are depreciated using the same rate as existing assets-in-place with a straight-line depreciation method.Item#29of Compustat represents the number of company workers(in-cluding all employees of consolidated domestic and foreign subsidiaries,all part-time and seasonal employees,full-time equivalent employees,and offi-cers,and excluding consultants,contract workers,directors,and employees of unconsolidated subsidiaries)as reported to shareholders.5The amount of salary expense is a better variable to capture the amount of investment in labor than the number of employees,especially when the scaling variable is the book value of assets.However,only about20%offirm years in Com-pustat report a nonmissing labor expense(#42),but about95%of thefirm 5Thisfigure is reported by somefirms as an average number of employees and by others as the number of employees at year end.If both are given,the year-endfigure is used.There is no reason to believe that this difference introduces a systematic bias to our estimates.728F.LIyears have the number of employees(#29).Using the number of employ-ees therefore can increase the number of observations dramatically.The number of employees scaled by the book value of assets captures the labor intensity(i.e.,the number of employees per dollar of assets).To the ex-tent that the salary per employee remains relatively stable over time for the samefirm,scaling the number of employees by total assets is not a problem. In unreported analysis,I also redo all the tests by replacing the dependent variable in equation(1)with log(NEMP t/NEMP t−1)and the results are sim-ilar.I use afirm-level regression because managerial decisions most natu-rally apply at thefirm level.I expect that afirm-level specification is bet-ter than cross-sectional specifications because the regression coefficients are likely to differ acrossfirms because managers havefirm-specific infor-mation about future profitability.TheβL andβC are the“response coef-ficients”of corporate investment level to current reported earnings.For a firm to haveβL andβC estimated in year t,it needs to have nonmissing data in the10years from t−9to t to estimate equations(1)and(2). Because this regression approach uses10years of rolling data and there-fore shrinks the sample size greatly,I also construct two other measures of earnings quality based on investment decisions forfirm i in year T as follows:γL,iT=(NEMP iT−NEMP i,T−1)/(E iT−E i,T−1)(4) andγC,iT=(CAPX iT+RND iT−CAPX i,T−1−RND i,T−1)/(E iT−E i,T−1),(5) where all the definitions of the variables are the same as in equations(1) and(2).Thus,γL andγC capture the response of investment to the change in earnings in a given pared withβL andβC,the advantage of these measures is that they require only two years of data,but the cost is that they might not measure the association between earnings and investment precisely and that it is more difficult to interpret the measures when the change in earnings is negative.6Also,I construct two measures that combine the information content of both the capital and labor investment decisions.To smooth out any possible nonlinear effect of the variables,I average the measures based on capital and labor decisions using their decile ranksEQ1=(Decile(βL)+(Decile(βC))/2(6) andEQ2=(Decile(γL)+(Decile(γC))/2,(7) where De cile(·)is the decile rank of a variable in a year.6This is especially true during recession years.EARNINGS QUALITY AND CORPORATE INVESTMENT729T A B L E1Summary StatisticsStandard25th50th75thVariable N Mean Deviation Pctl Pctl Pctl p-Value βC34,5940.1870.561−0.0800.1420.4260.00 RSQ C34,5940.1660.1850.0220.0960.252–βL34,5940.0350.0670.0000.0130.0480.00 RSQ L34,5940.2230.2230.0350.1470.355–γC83,8480.209 1.584−0.4420.1620.9820.00γL83,8480.0500.533−0.0090.0090.0780.00 DD34,5940.0240.0160.0120.0200.031–ABSACC83,8480.0600.0600.0200.0430.080–VOL CFO34,5940.0600.0320.0360.0530.077–VOL ACC34,5940.0520.0300.0290.0450.067–VOL EARN34,5940.0440.0290.0230.0380.058–βR28,948 3.234 5.8150.328 1.678 4.3910.00 SALGRW34,5940.0880.0640.0480.0850.125–MTB74,348 1.506 1.4220.960 1.183 1.640–OPCYC77,1000.0510.5490.0140.0200.036–DIV83,6280.7020.458011–This table presents the summary statistics of the investment-based earnings-quality measures and other variables.The p-value is for the test that examines whether the variable is significantly different from zero.TheβC is estimated for everyfirm year as the slope coefficient from the regression of change in capital and R&D expenditures(scaled by lagged book value of assets)on the change in reported earnings(adjusted for the impact of current capital and R&D expenditures and scaled by lagged book value of assets)using data from the last10years.The RSQ C is the adjusted R-squared from the regression.TheβL is estimated for everyfirm year as the slope coefficient from the regression of change in the number of employees (scaled by lagged book value of assets)on the change in reported earnings(scaled by lagged book value of assets)using data from the last10years.The RSQ L is the adjusted R-squared from the regression.For afirm year to haveβC andβL,it must have nonmissing data for the last10years.TheγC is the change in capital and R&D expenditures divided by the change in reported earnings.TheγL is the change in the number of employees divided by the change in reported earnings.The DD is estimated for everyfirm year as the standard deviation of the Dechow and Dichev[2002]residuals from the regression of accruals on lagged CFO(operating cashflows),current CFO,and next year’s CFO using the last10years of data.The ABSACC is the absolute amount of accruals scaled by lagged book value of assets.The VOL CFO,VOL ACC, and VOL EARN are the volatility of operating cashflows,accruals,and earnings(all scaled by lagged book value of assets)calculated using data from the last10years.TheβR is estimated for everyfirm year as the slope coefficients from the regression of stock returns on the change in reported earnings(scaled by lagged book value of assets)using data from the last10years.The SALGRW is the average sales growth in the last 10years.The MTB is the market value of afirm’s asset divided by the book value of the assets.The OPCYC is the operating cycle of afirm,calculated as360/(Sales Average AR)+360/((Cost of Goods Sold)/(Average Inventory)).The DIV is a dummy variable that equals1if afirm pays dividend and0otherwise.To summarize,βL,βC,and E Q1(i.e.,the decile rank average ofβL andβC)capture the earnings quality inferred from labor-and capital-investment decisions by using a regression approach;γL,γC,and E Q2(i.e., the decile rank average ofγL andγC)represent the response of corporate investments to earnings innovation in the current year.3.2SUMMARY STATISTICSTable1presents the summary statistics of the investment-based earnings-quality measures and other variables needed in later analysis.Every year, if afirm has nonmissing data for the past10years,itsβL is the estimation of the slope coefficient in the regression of the change in employment on the change in earnings following equation(1),andβC is the estimation of730F.LIthe slope coefficient in the regression of the change in capital investment on the change in earnings using equation(2).Because of the10-year data requirement,the sample size is relatively small(34,594firm years or about 800firms per year).7As predicted,current changes in reported earnings positively relate to the contemporaneous changes in the level of labor and capital.As indi-cated in table1,the mean coefficient on earnings change in the labor re-gression(βL)is0.035and the median is0.013.The mean and median of βC are0.187and0.142,respectively.The RSQ L and RSQ C are the adjustedR-squared from the regressions that have a mean of0.223and0.166,re-spectively,and indicate that earnings changes can explain17–22%of the variations in the changes of labor and capital investment.Based on the cross-sectional distribution of the coefficients,βL andβC are both statisti-cally significant with p-values of0.00.The variations in the two measures are substantial:the standard deviations ofβL andβC are0.067and0.561and their inter-quartile ranges are0.048and0.506,respectively.Table1also presents the summary statistics ofγL andγC,the estimates of earnings quality defined in equations(4)and(5).Because the estimates only require two years of data,the sample size is much bigger—83,848firm years(or about2,000firms per year).TheγL andγC have a mean of0.050 and0.209,respectively and both have substantial variations with standard deviations of0.533and1.584.The table also presents the summary statistics of other commonly used measures of earnings quality.The DD is the standard deviation of accruals that cannot be explained by cashflows as defined in Dechow and Dichev [2002],and is calculated using data from the last10years.TheβR is the earnings–returns association calculated as the slope coefficient in the re-gression of stock returns on the change in reported earnings using data from the last10years.The ABSACC is the absolute amount of accruals scaled by lagged book value of assets.The V OL CF O,V OL ACC,and V OL E ARN are the volatilities of cashflows,accruals,and earnings(all scaled by lagged book value of assets)calculated using data from the last10 years.3.3INVESTMENT-BASED EARNINGS QUALITY AND OTHER MEASURESOF EARNINGS QUALITYIn this subsection,I examine the associations between the earnings-quality measures developed in this paper(i.e.,βL,βC,γL,andγC)andfirm characteristics and other earnings-quality measures,such as the Dechow and Dichev[2002]measure,absolute value of accruals,volatility of earn-ings,earnings–returns association,growth,market-to-book ratio,andfirm operating cycle.Table2presents the Pearson correlation coefficients be-tween the investment-based earnings-quality measures and these variables.7To remove the influence of extreme observations,all variables are winsorized at the1% and99%levels.。

企业盈利质量分析中英文对照外文翻译文献

企业盈利质量分析中英文对照外文翻译文献

企业盈利质量分析中英文对照外文翻译文献(文档含英文原文和中文翻译)原文:Measuring the quality of earnings1. IntroductionGenerally accepted accounting principles (GAAP) offer some flexibility in preparing the financial statements and give the financial managers some freedom to select among accounting policies and alternatives. Earning management uses the flexibility in financial reporting to alter the financial results of the firm (Ortega and Grant, 2003).In other words, earnings management is manipulating the earning to achieve apredetermined target set by the management. It is a purposeful intervention in the external reporting process with the intent of obtaining some private gain (Schipper, 1989).Levit (1998) defines earning management as a gray area where the accounting is being perverted; where managers are cutting corners; and, where earnings reports reflect the desires of management rather than the underlying financial performance of the company.The popular press lists several instances of companies engaging in earnings management. Sensormatic Electronics, which stamped shipping dates and times on sold merchandise, stopped its clocks on the last day of a quarter until customer shipments reached its sales goal. Certain business units of Cendant Corporation inflated revenues nearly $500 million just prior to a merger; subsequently, Cendant restated revenues and agreed with the SEC to change revenue recognition practices. AOL restated earnings for $385 million in improperly deferred marketing expenses. In 1994, the Wall Street Journal detailed the many ways in which General Electric smoothed earnings, including the careful timing of capital gains and the use of restructuring charges and reserves, in response to the article, General Electric reportedly received calls from other corporations questioning why such common practices were “front-page” news.Earning management occurs when managers use judgment in financial reporting and in structuring transactions to alter financial reports to either mislead some stakeholders about the underlying economic performance of the company or to influence contractual outcomes that depend on reported accounting numbers (Healy and Whalen, 1999).Magrath and Weld (2002) indicate that abusive earnings management and fraudulent practices begins by engaging in earnings management schemes designed primarily to “smooth” earnings to meet internally or externally imposed earnings forecasts and analysts’ expectations.Even if earnings management does not explicitly violate accounting rules, it is an ethically questionable practice. An organization that manages its earnings sends amessage to its employees that bending the truth is an acceptable practice. Executives who partake of this practice risk creating an ethical climate in which other questionable activities may occur. A manager who asks the sales staff to help sales one day forfeits the moral authority to criticize questionable sales tactics another day.Earnings management can also become a very slippery slope, which relatively minor accounting gimmicks becoming more and more aggressive until they create material misstatements in the financial statements (Clikeman, 2003)The Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) issued three staff accounting bulletins (SAB) to provide guidance on some accounting issues in order to prevent the inappropriate earnings management activities by public companies: SAB No. 99 “Materiality”, SAB No. 100 “Restructuring and Impairment Charges” and SAB No. 101 “Revenue Recognition”.Earnings management behavior may affect the quality of accounting earnings, which is defined by Schipper and Vincent (2003) as the extent to which the reported earnings faithfully represent Hichsian economic income, which is the amount that can be consumed (i.e. paid out as dividends) during a period, while leaving the firm equally well off at the beginning and the end of the period.Assessment of earning quality requires sometimes the separations of earnings into cash from operation and accruals, the more the earnings is closed to cash from operation, the higher earnings quality. As Penman (2001) states that the purpose of accounting quality analysis is to distinguish between the “hard” numbers resulting from cash flows and the “soft” numbers resulting from accrual accounting.The quality of earnings can be assessed by focusing on the earning persistence; high quality earnings are more persistent and useful in the process of decision making.Beneish and Vargus (2002) investigate whether insider trading is informative about earnings quality using earning persistence as a measure for the quality of earnings, they find that income-increasing accruals are significantly more persistent for firms with abnormal insider buying and significantly less persistent for firms with abnormal insider selling, relative to firms which there is no abnormal insider trading.Balsam et al. (2003) uses the level of discretionary accruals as a direct measurefor earning quality. The discretionary accruals model is based on a regression relationship between the change in total accruals as dependent variable and change in sales and change in the level of property, plant and equipment, change in cash flow from operations and change in firm size (total assets) as independent variables. If the regression coefficients in this model are significant that means that there is earning management in that firm and the earnings quality is low.This research presents an empirical study on using three different approaches of measuring the quality of earnings on different industry. The notion is; if there is a complete consistency among the three measures, a general assessment for the quality of earnings (high or low) can be reached and, if not, the quality of earnings is questionable and needs different other approaches for measurement and more investigations and analysis.The rest of the paper is divided into following sections: Earnings management incentives, Earnings management techniques, Model development, Sample and statistical results, and Conclusion.2. Earnings management incentives2.1 Meeting analysts’ expectationsIn general, analysts’ expectations and company predictions tend to address two high-profile components of financial performance: revenue and earnings from operations.The pressure to meet revenue expectations is particularly intense and may be the primary catalyst in leading managers to engage in earning management practices that result in questionable or fraudulent revenue recognition practices. Magrath and Weld (2002) indicate that improper revenue recognition practices were the cause of one-third of all voluntary or forced restatements of income filed with the SEC from 1977 to 2000.Ironically, it is often the companies themselves that create this pressure to meet the market’s earnings expec tations. It is common practice for companies to provide earnings estimates to analysts and investors. Management is often faced with the task of ensuring their targeted estimates are met.Several companies, including Coca-Cola Co., Intel Corp., and Gillette Co., have taken a contrary stance and no longer provide quarterly and annual earnings estimates to analysts. In doing so, these companies claim they have shifted their focus from meeting short-term earnings estimates to achieving their long-term strategies (Mckay and Brown, 2002).2.2 To avoid debt-covenant violations and minimize political costsSome firms have the incentive to avoid violating earnings-based debt covenants. If violated, the lender may be able to raise the interest rate on the debt or demand immediate repayment. Consequently, some firms may use earnings-management techniques to increase earnings to avoid such covenant violations. On the other hand, some other firms have the incentive to lower earnings in order to minimize political costs associated with being seen as too profitable. For example, if gasoline prices have been increasing significantly and oil companies are achieving record profit level, then there may be incentive for the government to intervene and enact an excess-profit tax or attempt to introduce price controls.2.3 To smooth earnings toward a long-term sustainable trendFor many years it has been believed that a firm should attempt to reduce the volatility in its earnings stream in order to maximize share price. Because a highly violate earning pattern indicates risk, therefore the stock will lose value compared to others with more stable earnings patterns. Consequently, firms have incentives to manage earnings to help achieve a smooth and growing earnings stream (Ortega and Grant, 2003).2.4 Meeting the bonus plan requirementsHealy (1985) provides the evidence that earnings are managed in the direction that is consistent with maximizing executives’ earnings-based bonus. When earnings will be below the minimum level required to earn a bonus, then earning are managed upward so that the minimum is achieved and a bonus is earned. Conversely, when earning will be above the maximum level at which no additional bonus is paid, then earnings are managed downward. The extra earnings that will not generate extra bonus this current period are saved to be used to earn a bonus in a future period.When earnings are between the minimum and the maximum levels, then earnings are managed upward in order to increase the bonus earned in the current period.2.5 Changing managementEarnings management usually occurs around the time of changing management, the CEO of a company with poor performance indicators will try to increase the reported earnings in order to prevent or postpone being fired. On the other hand, the new CEO will try shift part of the income to future years around the time when his/her performance will be evaluated and measured, and blame the low earning at the beginning of his contract on the acts of the previous CEO.3. Earnings management techniquesOne of the most common earnings management tools is reporting revenue before the seller has performed under the terms of a sales contract (SEC,SAB No. 101,1999).Another area of concern is where a company fails to comply with GAAP and inappropriately records restructuring charges and general reserves for future losses, reversing or relieving reserves in inappropriate periods, and recognizing or not recognizing an asset impairment charge in the appropriate period (SEC, SAB No. 100, 1999).Managers can influence reported expenses through assumptions and estimates such as the assumed rate of return on pension plan asset and the estimated useful lives of fixed assets, also they can influence reported earnings by controlling the timing of purchasing, deliveries, discretionary expenditures, and sale of assets.3.1 Big bath“Big Bath” charges are one-time restructuring charge. Current earnings will be decreased by overstating these one-time charges. By reversing the excessive reserve, future earnings will increase.Big bath charges are not always related to restructuring. In April 2001, Cisco Systems Inc. announced charges against earnings of almost $4 billion. The bulk of the charge, $2.5 billion, consisted of an inventory write down. Writing off more than a billion dollars from inventory now means more than a billion dollars of less cost in the future period. This an example of what ultra-conservative accounting in oneperiod makes possible in future periods.3.2 Abuse of materialityAnother area that might be used by accountants to manipulate the earning is the application of materiality principle in preparing the financial statements, this principle is very wide, flexible and has no specific range to determine where the item is material or not. SEC uses the interpretation ruled by the supreme court in identifying what is material; the supreme court has held that a fact is material if there is a substantial likelihood that the fact would have been viewed by reasonable investor as having significan tly altered the “total mix” of information made available (SEC, SAB No. 99, 1999).The SEC has also introduced some considerations for a quantitatively small misstatement of a financial statement item to be material:. whether the misstatement arises from an item capable of precise measurement or whether it arises from an estimate and, if so, the degree of imprecision inherent in the estimate;. whether the misstatement masks a change in earnings or other trends;.whether the misstatement hides a failure to meet analysts’ consensus expectations for the enterprise;. whether the misstatement changes a loss into income or vice versa;. whether the misstatement concerns a segment or other portion of the registrant’s business that has been identified as playing a significant role in the registrant’s operations or profitability; and. whether the misstatement involves concealment of an unlawful transaction.3.3 Cookie jar“Cookie jar” reserve –sometimes labeled rainy day reserve or contingency reserves, in periods of strong financial performance, cookie jar reserve enable to reduce earnings by overstating reserves, overstating expenses, and using one-time write-offs. In periods of weak financial performance, cookie jar reserves can be used to increase earnings by reversing accruals and reserves to reduce current period expenses (Kokoszka, 2003).The most famous example of use of cookie jar reserves is WorldCom Inc. In August 2002, an internal review revealed that the company had $2.5 billion reserves related to litigation, uncollectible and taxes. The company used most of them in a series of so-called reserve reversals in order to have higher earnings.Source: Khaled ElMoatasem Abdelghany,2005. “Measuring the quality of earnings”, Managerial Auditing Journal, vol.20, no.9, pp.1001 – 1015.译文:衡量盈利质量1、引言一般公认会计原则(GAAP)提供准备一定的灵活性的财务报表,给财务经理一定的自由空间进行选择会计政策和方案。

earnings 收益

earnings 收益
• Discriminace offers different opportunities to similar individuals who differ only by race, ethnic group, sex, age, or other personal characteristics.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western
Above-Equilibrium Wages: Minimum-Wage Laws, Unions, and Efficiency Wages
• Why are some workers’ wages set above the level that brings supply and demand into equilibrium?
Copyright © 2004 South-Western
Human Capital
• Education represents an expenditure of resources at one point in time to raise productivity in the future. • By the year 2000, a man with a college degree earned more than 89 percent more than without one. Women showed a 70 percent increase in earnings due to a college degree.
Earnings and Discrimination
19
Copyright©2004 South-Western
Earnings and Discrimination

资产评估英语

资产评估英语

资产评估英语第一篇:资产评估英语liabilities evaluation 负债评估restore replacement cost 复原重置成本renewal replacement cost 更新重置成本non-patent technique and know-how 非专利技术和秘诀rate of risk return on investment 风险报酬率personal estate 动产equal expedient method 对等权宜法adjustment coefficient of road condition 车辆行驶路况调整系数purchase cost of vehicle 车辆购置费long term investment evaluation 长期投资评估newness rate 成新率real estate 不动产product and store goods evaluation 产成品和库存商品的评估transfer of property right 产权转让change of property right 产权变动principle of property right interests subject alteration 产权利益主体变动原则reference object 参照物material evaluation 材料评估earning ratio of capital 本金化率quote 报价variable factor adjustment method 变动因素调整法key-point evaluation method 重点评估法engineering process method with recomposed budge 重编预算工程进度法replacement cost calculation method 重置核算法replacement cost method 重置成本法tangible assets 有形资产physical wear 有形损耗Sino-foreign cooperative business operation 中外合作经营Sino-foreign joint venture 中外合资经营intellectual property right 知识产权expected service life 预计使用年限(有效使用寿命)evaluation of construction engineering in process 在建工程评估construction engineering in process 在建工程evaluation of products in process 在产品评估conversion rate 折现率discount to present value 折现enterprise total assets evaluation 整体企业资产评估total assets of enterprise 整体企业资产duties of increase in value 增值税travelled distance 已行驶里程inquiry 询价intangible asset evaluation 无形资产评估earnings of intangible assets 无形资产收益额intangible assets 无形资产moral wear 无形损耗special privilege evaluation 特许权评估special privilege 特许权益inflation rate 通货膨胀率consumption tax 消费税current market price method 现行市价法current market price 现行市价shop survey 现场勘查price index method 物价指数法(指数调整法)price index 物价指数evaluation of right of use land 土地使用权评估right of use land 土地使用权land ownership 土地所有权practical serviced life 实际已使用年限claim 索赔present earning value method 收益现值法present value of earning 收益现值evaluation of trade mark right 商标权评估trade mark 商标trade credit evaluation 商誉评估trade credit 商誉market of equipment transfer 设备调剂市场equipment sublet out 设备租出equipment sublet in 设备租入adjustment coefficient of equipment work condition 设备工作状态调整系数sale of equipment 设备出售equipment purchasing 设备采购installation and test cost of equipment 设备安装调试费transportation cost of equipment 设备运杂费equipment leasing with circulating funds 设备融资租赁life of equipment 设备寿命disposal cost of facilities 设备清理费adjustment coefficient of equipment utilization 设备利用调系数liquidation price method 清算价格法liquidation price 清算价格circulating assets 流动资产nominal serviced life 名义已使用年限book value method 历史成本法(FOB)free on board 离岸价verification and affirmation of assets evaluation 资产评估的验证确认inassignable assets 不可确指的资产devaluation by real degradation 实体性陈旧贬值engineering process method 工程进度法function and cost method 功能成本法devaluation by functional degradation 功能性陈旧贬值fair price 公允价格scale economical profit index analysis method 规模经济效益指数分析法contract 合同rights and interests of contract 合同权益insurance of ocean transportation 海运保险费ocean transportation cost 海运费exchange rate 汇率time value of money 货币时间价值machine equipment evaluation 机器设备评估simple age limit method 简单年限法price adjustment factor 价格调整系数acceptance 接受building 建筑物replacement cost of building 建筑物重置价functional devaluation of building 建筑物功能性贬值economical devaluation of building 建筑物经济性贬值building evaluation 建筑物评估import duties 进口关税economic devaluation 经济性贬值assignable assets 可确指的资产item request of assets evaluation 评估立项申请effective period of assets evaluation 评估有效期base date of assets evaluation 评估基准日links of evaluation 评估环节joint operation of enterprises 企业联营liquidation of enterprise 企业清算sale of enterprise 企业出售joint-stock system operation of enterprise 企业股份制经营annexation of enterprise 企业兼并resources assets 资源性资产resources assets evaluation 资源性资产评估original book value of assets 资产原值net book value assets 资产净值purpose of assets evaluation 资产评估目的 5 salient features of assets evaluation 资产评估特点basis of assets evaluation 资产评估依据subject of assets evaluation 资产评估主体operating procedure of assets evaluation 资产评估[操作]程序(法定程序)work principle of assets evaluation 资产评估[工作]原则written report of assets evaluation 资产评估报告书statutes system of assets evaluation 资产评估法规体系method of assets evaluation 资产评估方法assets evaluation management 资产评估管理assets evaluation organization 资产评估机构hypothesis of assets evaluation 资产评估假设operation principle of assets evaluation 资产评估经济性(操作性)原则object of assets evaluation 资产评估客体(对象)check and arbitration of assets evaluation 资产评估的复核仲裁function of assets evaluation 资产评估的功能assets evaluation files 资产评估档案integrated age limit method 综合年限法integrated remainder life 综合剩余寿命integrated service life 综合服役年限certified public assets estimator 注册资产评估师patent 专利evaluation of patent right 专利权评估assignment of the patent right 专利权转让know-how evaluation 专用技术(诀窍)评估statistical analysis method 点面推算法single assets 单项资产(CIF)cost insurance and freight 到岸价system of land price 地产友情链接现金 Cash in hand银行存款 Cash in bank其他货币资金-外埠存款Other monetary assetscashier‘s check其他货币资金-银行汇票 Other monetary assetscredit cards其他货币资金-信用证保证金Other monetary assetscash for investment短期投资-股票投资 Investmentsstocks短期投资-债券投资 Investmentsbonds短期投资-基金投资 Investmentsfunds短期投资-其他投资 Investmentsothers短期投资跌价准备 Provision for short-term investment长期股权投资-股票投资 Long term equity investmentothers长期债券投资-债券投资 Long term securities investemntothers 长期投资减值准备 Provision for long-term investment应收票据 Notes receivable应收股利 Dividends receivable应收利息 Interest receivable应收帐款 Trade debtors坏帐准备-应收帐款 Provision for doubtful debtsother debtors 其他流动资产 Other current assets物资采购 Purchase原材料 Raw materials包装物 Packing materials低值易耗品 Low value consumbles材料成本差异 Material cost difference自制半成品 Self-manufactured goods库存商品 Finished goods商品进销差价Difference between purchase & sales of commodities委托加工物资 Consigned processiong material委托代销商品 Consignment-out受托代销商品 Consignment-in分期收款发出商品 Goods on instalment sales存货跌价准备 Provision for obsolete stocks待摊费用 Prepaid expenses待处理流动资产损益 Unsettled G/L on current assets待处理固定资产损益 Unsettled G/L on fixed assets委托贷款-本金 Consignment loaninterest委托贷款-减值准备 Consignment loanBuildings固定资产-机器设备Fixed assetsElectronic Equipment,furniture and fixtures固定资产-运输设备 Fixed assetsspecific materials工程物资-专用设备 Project materialprepaid for equipment工程物资-为生产准备的工具及器具 Project materialpatent无形资产-非专利技术 Intangible assetstrademark rights无形资产-土地使用权Intangible assetsShort termShort termShort termLong term应付债券-债券面值 Bond payableExcess应付债券-债券折价 Bond payableAccrued interest长期应付款 Long term payable专项应付款 Specific payable其他长期负债 Other long term liabilities应交税金-所得税 Tax payablebusiness tax应交税金-消费税 Tax payableothers递延税款贷项 Deferred taxation credit股本 Share capital已归还投资 Investment returned利润分配-其他转入Profit appropriationstatutory surplus reserve利润分配-提取法定公益金 Profit appropriationreserve fund利润分配-提取企业发展基金Profit appropriationstaff bonus and welfare fund利润分配-利润归还投资 Profit appropriationpreference shares dividends利润分配-提取任意盈余公积Profit appropriationordinary shares dividends利润分配-转作股本的普通股股利Profit appropriationshare premium资本公积-接受捐赠非现金资产准备Capital surpluscash donation资本公积-股权投资准备 Capital surplussubsidiary资本公积-外币资本折算差额 Capital surplusothers盈余公积-法定盈余公积金Surplus reserveother surplus reserve盈余公积-法定公益金 Surplus reservereserve fund盈余公积-企业发展基金Surplus reservereture investment by investment主营业务收入 Sales 主营业务成本 Cost of sales主营业务税金及附加 Sales tax营业费用 Operating expenses管理费用 General and administrative expenses财务费用 Financial expenses投资收益 Investment income其他业务收入 Other operating income营业外收入 Non-operating income补贴收入 Subsidy income其他业务支出 Other operating expenses营业外支出 Non-operating expenses所得税 Income tax直接人工成本差异(direct labor variance)直接材料成本差异(direct material variance)在产品计价(work-in-process costing)联产品成本计算(joint products costing)生产成本汇总程序(accumulation process of procluction cost)制造费用差异(manufacturing expenses variance)实际成本与估计成本(actual cost and estimated cost)工资费用分配(salary costs allocation)成本曲线(cost curve)农业生产成本(agriculture production cost)原始成本和重置成本(original cost and replacement cost)工程施工成本直接成本与间接成本(direct cost and indirect cost)可控成本(controllable cost)制造费用分配(manufacturing expenses allocation)理论成本与应用成本(theory cost and practice cost)辅助生产成本分配(auxiliary production cost allocation)期间,费用成本控制程序(procedure of cost control)成本记录(cost entry,cost recorder cost agenda)成本计算分批法(job costing method)直接人工成本差异(direct labor variance)成本控制方法(cost control method)内河运输成本生产费用要素(elements of production expenses)历史成本与未来成本(historical cost and future cost)可避免成本与不可避免成本(avoidable cost and unavoidable cost)成本计算期(cost period)平均成本与个别成本(avorage cost and individual cost)跨期摊提费用分配(inter-period expenses allocation)计划成本(planned cost)数量差异(quantity variance)燃料费用分配(fuel expenses allocation)定额成本控制制度(norm cost control system)定额管理(management norm)可递延成本与不可递延成本(deferrable cost and undeferrable cost)成本控制标准(standard of cost control)副产品成本计算(by-product costing)责任成本(responsibility cost)生产损失核算(production loss accounting)生产成本(production cost)预计成本(predicted cost)成本结构(cost structure)房地产开发成本主要成本与加工成本(prime costs and processing costs)决策成本(cost of decision making)成本计算品种法(category costing method)在产品成本(work-in-process cost)工厂成本(factory cost)成本考核(cost assess)制造费用(manufactruing expenses)动力费用分配(power expenses allocation)趋势分析法(trend analysis approach)成本计算简单法(simple costing method)责任成本层次(levels of responsibility cost)对比分析法(comparative analysis approach)约当产量比例法(equivalent units method)原始记录(original record)可比产品成本分析(general product cost analysis)成本计算方法(costing method)成本计算对象(costing objective)成本计算单位(costing unit)成本计划完成情况分析成本计划管理体系(planned management system of cost)成本计划(cost plan)成本会计(cost accounting)成本核算原则(principle of costing)成本核算程序(cost accounting qrocedures)成本核算成本(costing account)成本核算(costing)成本归集(cost accumulation)成本管理(cost management)成本分析(cost analysis)成本分配(ocst allocation)成本分类账(cost ledger)成本分类(cost classifiction)成本费用界限成本调整(cost adjustment)成本差异(cost variance)成本报告(costing report)成本(cost)车间成本(workshop cost)厂内经济核算制(internal business accounting system)厂内结算价格(internal settlement prices)产品寿命周期成本(product life cycle cost)产品成本项目(cost items of product)产品成本技术经济分析产品成本计划(the plan of product costs)产品成本(product cost)汇总原始凭证(cumulative source document)汇总记账凭证核算形式(bookkeeping procedure using summary ovchers)工作底稿(working paper)复式记账凭证(mvltiple account titles voucher)复式记账法(Double entry bookkeeping)复合分录(compound entry)划线更正法(correction by drawing a straight ling)汇总原始凭证(cumulative source document)会计凭证(accounting documents)会计科目表(chart of accounts)会计科目(account title)红字更正法(correction by using red ink)会计核算形式(bookkeeping procedures)过账(posting)会计致迹╝ccounting entry)会计循环(accounting cycle)会计账簿(Book of accounts)活页式账簿(loose-leaf book)集合分配账户(clearing accounts)计价对比账户(matching accounts)记账方法(bookkeeping methods)记账规则(recording rules)记账凭证(voucher)记账凭证核算形式(Bookkeeping proced ureusing vouchers)记账凭证汇总表核算形式(bookkeeping procedure using categorized account summary)简单分录(simple entry)结算账户(settlement accounts)结账(closing account)结账分录(closing entry)借贷记账法(debit-credit bookkeeping)通用日记账核算形式(bookkeeping procedure using general journal)外来原始凭证(source document from outside)现金日记账(cash journal)虚账户(nominal accounts)序时账簿(book of chronological entry)一次凭证(single-record document)银行存款日记账(deposit journal)永续盘存制(perpetual inventory system)原始凭证(source document)暂记账户(suspense accounts)增减记账法(increase-decrease bookkeeping)债权结算账户(accounts for settlement of claim)债权债务结算账户(accounts for settlement of claim and debt)债务结算账户(accounts for settlement of debt)账户(account)账户编号(Account number)账户对应关系(debit-credit relationship)账项调整(adjustment of account)专用记账凭证(special-purpose voucher)转回分录(reversing entry)资金来源账户(accounts of sources of funds)资产负债账户(balance sheet accounts)转账凭证(transfer voucher)资金运用账户(accounts of applications of funds)自制原始凭证(internal source document)总分类账簿(general ledger)总分类账户(general account)附加账户(adjunct accounts)付款凭证(payment voucher)分类账簿(ledger)中级会计固定资产(fixed assets)利润总额利益分配(profit distribution)应计费用(accrued expense)商标权(trademarks and tradenames)净利润(net income)应付利润(profit payable)收益债券(income bonds)利息资本化(capitalization of interests)预付账款(advance to supplier)其他应收款(other receivables)现金(cash)公司债券发行(corporate bond floatation)应付工资(wages payable)实收资本(paid-in capital)盈余公积(surplus reserves)股利(dividend)应交税金(taxes payable)负商誉(negative goodwill)费用的确认(recognition of expense)短期投资(temporary investment)专有技术(know-how)专营权(franchises)资本公积(capital reserves)自然资源(natural resources)存货(inventory)偿债基金(sinking fund)长期应付款(long-term payables)长期投资(long-term investments)长期借款(long-term loans)长期负债(long-term liability of long-term debt)财务费用(financing expenses)拨定留存收益(appropriated retained earnings)标准成本法(standard costing)变动成本法(variable costing)版权(copyrights)高级会计期货交易市场(market of futures transaction)期货交易(futures transaction)举债经营融资租赁(leveraged lease)金融工具(financial instruments)企业集团(business qroup)年度报告(annual report)内部往来(transactions between home office and branches)合伙企业(partnership enterprise)合并资产负债表(consolidated balance sheet)合并主体的所得税会计(accounting for income taxes of consolidated entities)(美)合并现金流量表(consolidated statement of cash flow)合并价差(cost-book value differentials)合并会计报表(consolidated financial statements)购买法(purchase methed)企业整体价值(the value of an enterprise as a whole)权益结合法(pooling of interest method)期内所得税分摊(intraperiod tax allocation)(美)期末存货的未实现损益(unrealized profit in ending inventory)公司间的长期资产业务(intercompany transactions in long-term assets)名义货币保全(maintaining capital in units of money)基金论(the fund theory)功能性货币(functional currency)(汇兑损益(exchange gains or losses)合并财务状况变动表(consolidated statement of changes in financial poition)换算损益(translation gains or losses)举债经营收购(Leveraged buyouts,简称LBC)(美)母公司持股比例变动(change in ownership percentage held by parent)交互分配法(reciprocal allocation approach)(美)货币项(monetary items)合伙清算(partnership liquidation全面分摊法(comprehensive allocation)固定资产投资方向调节税合并费用(expenses related to combinations)间接标价法(indirect quotation)买入汇率(buying rate)期货合约(futrues contract)混合合并(conglomeration)控投公司(holding company)股票指数期货(stock index futrues)横向销售(crosswise sale)固定汇率(fixed rate)纳税影响法(tax effect method)记账汇率(recording rate)横向合并(horizontal integration)合并前股利(preacquisition dividends)可变现净值(net realizable)企业合并会计(accounting for business combination)平仓盈亏(offset gain and loss)卖出汇率(selling rate)金融期货交易(financial futures transaction)会计利润(accounting income)合并损益表(consolidated income statement)公允价值(fair value)期权(options)间接控股(indirect holding)两笔交易观(two-transaction opinion)破产清算(bankrupcy liquidation)企业合并(business combination)企业论(the enterprise theory)商品寄销(consignment)个人所得税(personal income tax)个人财务报表(personal financial state-ments)(美)改组计划(reorganization plan)(美)改组(reorganization)复杂权益法(complex equity method)附属公司(associated company)负权人偿金(dividend)浮动汇率(floating rate)分支机构会计(accounting for branch)推定赎回损益(constructive gains and losses on bonds)推定赎回(constructive retirement)投机(spculation)贴水(discount)特定物价指数(specific price index)分支机构(branch)分期收款销货(installment sales)分次清算(installment liquidation)分部报告(segmental reporting)房地产收入(real estate revenue)房地产成本(cost of real setate)房地产(real estate)多种汇率法(multiply exchange rate)对境外实体的净投资(net investment in foreign entities)订量单位:(units of measurement)递延法(deffered method)当代理论(contemporary theory)单一汇率法(singal method)退休金(pension plan)退休金会计(accounting for pension plan)(美)退休金给付义务(pension benefit obligations)(美)外币(foreign currency)外币业务(foreign currency transaction)吸收合并(merger)物价变动会计(accounting for price changes)无偿债能力(insolvency)完全合并(full consolidation)物价指数(price index)物价变动(price changes)完全应计法(full accrual method)物价总指数(general price index)外汇期货交易(foreign exchange frtrues transaction)下推会计(push-down accounting)(美)先折算后调整法(translation-remeasurement method)现行成本/稳值货币会计(current cost/general purchasing power accountin)现行成本(crurent cost)现行成本会计(current cost accounting)先调整后折算法(remeasurement-translation method)销售代理处(sales agency)相互持股(mutual holdings)相对账户调节(reconciliation of home office and branch accounts)新合伙人入伙(admission of a new parther)向上销售(upstream sale)衍生金融工具(derivative financial instru-ments)销售式融资租赁(sales-type financing lease)向下销售(downstream sale)消费税(consumer tax)一笔交易观(one-transaction opinion)业主权论(the proprietorship theory)一般物价水准会计(general price level accounting)一般购买力单位(units of general purchasing power)招股说明书(prospectus)中间汇率(middle rate)中期报告(interim reporting)重置成本(replacement cost)转租赁(subleases)准改组(quasi-reorbganization)(美)资本保全(capital maintenance)资本化价值(capitalized value)资本因素(capital factor)资产负债法(asset/libility method)存货转让价格(inventory transfer price)创立合并(consolidation)出租人会计(accounting for leases-lessor)持有(产)损益(holding gains losses)持仓盈亏(opsition gain and loss)承租人会计(accounting for leases-leasee)成本回收法(cost recovery method)纵向合并(Vertical integration)综合变动(general change)子公司权益变动(change in ownership of a subsidiary)子公司(subsidiary company)资源税(resources tax)成本法(cost method)财产信托会计(fiduciary accounting)(美)财产税(property tax)部分分摊法(partial allocation)不合并子公司(unconsolidated subsidiaries)最低退休金负债(minimum liability)(美)租赁(leases)租金(rents)企业会计期权市场(option market)期货市场(future market)可转让定期存单市场(negotiable CDmarket)货币市场(money market)黄金市场(gold market)国有独资公司股份有限公司(company limited by shares)股份两合公司(limited pactnership)公司(company)二级市场(security secondary market)独资企业(sole proprietorship)店头市场(over-the-counter-market)承兑市场(acceptance market)拆借市场(lending market)财务制度(financial regulations)财务政策(financial policy)财务预测(financial forecast)财务控制(financial control)金融市场(financial market)财务决策(financial decision)财务监督(financial cupervision)财务计划(financial planning)财务活动(financial activities)财务管理组织(organization of financial management)一级市场(security primary market)无限责任公司(company of unlimited liability)外汇市场(foreign exchange market)贴现市场(dixcount market)企业组织形式(forms of enterprise organization)政府会计期权市场(option market)期货市场(future market)可转让定期存单市场(negotiable CDmarket)货币市场(money market)黄金市场(gold market)国有独资公司股份有限公司(company limited by shares)股份两合公司(limited pactnership)公司(company)二级市场(security secondary market)独资企业(sole proprietorship)店头市场(over-the-counter-market)承兑市场(acceptance market)拆借市场(lending market)财务制度(financial regulations)财务政策(financial policy)财务预测(financial forecast)财务控制(financial control)金融市场(financial market)财务决策(financial decision)财务监督(financial cupervision)财务计划(financial planning)财务活动(financial activities)财务管理组织(organization of financial management)一级市场(security primary market)无限责任公司(company of unlimited liability)外汇市场(foreign exchange market)贴现市场(dixcount market)企业组织形式(forms of enterprise organization)事业单位会计(accounting for non-profit organizations)事业单位固定资产(fixed assets for non-profit organizations)事业单位固定基金(fixed funds non-profit organizations)事业单位负债(liabilities for non-profit organizations)事业单位对外投资(outside investments for non-profit organizations)事业单位财务清算(liquidation of non-profit organization)上缴上级支出(payment to the higher authority)上级补助收入(grant from the higher authority)其他收入(miscellaneous gains)科学事业单位资产(scientific research instifutes‘assets)科学事业单位支出(scientific research institutes‘expenditures)科学事业单位预算(scientific research institutes‘budgeting)科学事业单位收入(scientific research institutes‘revenues)科学事业单位结余(scientific research institutes‘surplus)科学事业单位会计制度(accointing regulations for scientific research instifutes)科学事业单位会计报表分析(scientific research institutes-analysis of accounting statements)科学事业单位会计(sicentific research institute accounting)科学事业单位成本费用管理(scientific research institutes-cost maragement)科学事业单位财务制度(financial regulations for scientific research institutes)经营支出(orerating expense)经营收入(operating revenue)基金预算支出(fund budget expenditure)基金预算收入(fund budget revenue)基金预算结余(surplus of fund budget)国家预算(state budget)国家决算(final accounts of state revenue and expenditure)高等学校资产(colleges and universities assets)高等学校支出(colleges and universities expenditures)高等学校预算管理方式(budget management method of colleges and universities)高等学校收入(colleges and universities revenues)专用基金支出(expenditure on special purpose fund)专用基金收入(proceeds from special purpose fund)中华人民共和国预算法(the budge t law of the people‘s Republic of China)资金调拨支出(expenditure on allocated and transeferred fund)财政收入(public finance-revemue)财政净资产(public finance-net assets)财政负债(public finance-liabilities)财政补助收入(grant from the state)拨入专款(restricted appropriation)第二篇:资产评估《资产评估》考试方案——会计学本科《资产评估》考试方案一、考试目的为了适应资产评估行业对资产评估实践能力要求较高的现实形势,在《资产评估》课程的教学中增加了实习、实践环节的教学内容。

  1. 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
  2. 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
  3. 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。

Earnings quality in U.K. private firmsΙRay Ball a,* and Lakshmanan Shivakumar ba Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL 60637, USAb London Business School, Regent’s Park, London NW1 4SA, United KingdomAbstractUK private and public companies face substantially equivalent regulation on auditing, accounting standards and taxes. We hypothesize that private-company financial reporting nevertheless is lower quality due to different market demand, regulation notwithstanding. A large UK sample supports this hypothesis. Quality is operationalized using Basu’s (1997) time-series measure of timely loss recognition and a new accruals-based method. The result is not affected by controls for size, leverage, industry membership and auditor size, or by allowing endogenous listing choice. The result enhances understanding of private companies, which are predominant in the economy. It also provides insight into the economics of accounting standards.JEL Classification: M41; K22; N24Keywords: Earnings quality; conservatism; loss recognition; private firms; economics of accounting standards; earnings time series; accruals._________ΙWe are grateful for helpful comments from Sudipta Basu, Martin Casey, Greg Clinch, Gilad Livne, Jim Seida, Michelle Yetman, Jim Wahlen, Gregory Waymire (the referee), Jerold Zimmerman (the editor), and participants at the 2002 Annual Meeting of the American Accounting Asso ciation, University of Chicago, Indiana University, London Business School, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, University of Notre Dame and University of Toronto. Ball gratefully acknowledges financial support from the University of Chicago, Graduate S chool of Business.*Corresponding author. Present address: Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, 1101 East 58th Street, Chicago, IL 60637-1561; Phone: +1-773-834-5941; fax: +1-773-834-4585.E-mail address: ray.ball@ (R. Ball)Earnings Quality in U.K. Private Firms1. IntroductionWe examine timely loss recognition – an important attribute of financial reporting quality – in a large sample of U.K. private and public firms. Private company reporting is interesting in its own right, due to the predominance of private companies in the economy.1 The U.K. setting is parti cularly interesting, because U.K. private company reporting is subject to substantially equivalent regulatory provisions as public company reporting, whereas the markets for private and public financial reporting are substantially different. The U.K. therefore provides a rare opportunity to study the interaction between market and regulatory effects (Ball, Robin and Wu 2000, 2002; Ball 2001). We argue that the market demands lower quality financial reporting for private companies than for public companies, regulation notwithstanding, and report evidence consistent with that view. The result enhances our understanding of the economic role of accounting standards, an issue that is surprisingly neglected in the literature.Three principal features of the U.K. financial reporting regulations are substantially equivalent for private and public companies. First, the U.K. Companies Act requires all private and public companies to file annual financial statements that comply with the same accounting standards. Second, financial statements filed by U.K. private companies must be audited (there is an exemption for very small companies, but no firms in our sample qualify). Third, private and public companies are subject to the same tax laws. These are the major regulatory institutions for U.K. financial reporting, and they are substantially equivalent for public and private companies.1 Over 90% of registered U.K. companies are private (Companies House, U.K.). They constitute 99.9% of all private non-agricultural entities in 1993 Europe (Mulhern 1995). The Forbes list of the top 500 U.S. private companies (/private500/) includes 245 with revenues exceeding $1 billion in 2000. The U.S. Small Business Admin istration (/advo/stats/facts99.pdf) reports that in 1998 businesses with fewer than 500 employees accounted for 51% of US GDP, 47% of sales, and 53% of private nonfarm employment. The role of small firms in job creation, growth and innovation is widely debated; see Schumpeter (1934) and Acs (1996).Nevertheless, the market for financial reporting differs substantially between private and public companies. Private companies are more likely to resolve information asymmetry by an “insider access” model. They are less likely to use public financial statements in contracting with lenders, managers and other parties, and in primary and secondary equity transactions. Their financial reporting is correspondingly more likely to be influenced by taxation, dividend and other policies. These differences imply a demand for lower quality financial reporting.We interpret reporting quality in abstract terms as the usefulness of financial statements to investors, creditors, managers and all other parties contracting with the firm. Following Basu (1997), we measure a single but nevertheless important attribute of reporting quality: timeliness in financial-statement recognition of economic losses. Timely loss recognition increases financial statement usefulness generally, particularly in corporate governance and debt agreements. Governance is affected because timely loss recognition makes managers less likely to make investments they expect ex ante to be negative-NPV, and less likely to continue operating investments with ex post negative cash flows. Debt is affected because timely loss recognition provides more accurate ex ante information for loan pricing and more quickly triggers debt agreement rights (su ch as repricing, and restrictions on leverage, investment and dividends) from violating covenants based on ex post accounting ratios. We therefore argue that timely recognition of economic losses is an important attribute of financial reporting quality.2 Our principal result is that timely loss recognition is substantially less prevalent in private companies than in public companies, despite the groups facing equivalent regulatory rules. The result is apparent in both a test for transitory time-series components in income and a new test based on the relation between accruals and cash flow from operations. It is robust with respect to controls for size, leverage, industry and fiscal year-end (which influence the likelihood of2 The literature on timely loss recognition, conservatism and value relevance are discussed further in Section 2.3.2experiencing an economic loss) and for auditor firm size. It also is robust with respect to alternative definitions of both income (inclusion or exclusion of exceptional and/or extra-ordinary items) and operating cash flow (estimated from successive balance sheets or directly from cash flow statements), alternative estimation methods (Fama-MacBeth t-statistics, extent of data Winsorizing) and alternative model specifications (a selection model addressing endogeneity of the public/private choice). This result cannot be attributed to ris k or tax differences between private and listed firms. The lower timeliness of loss recognition observed in private companies relative to public companies, despite the substantive equivalence of their reporting rules, supports the view that market demand substantially determines important financial reporting properties.As financial reporting criteria, quality and usefulness differ from economic efficiency because they do not address optimality. Lower quality does not imply sub-optimality because it can arise from either lower demand for or higher cost of supplying quality. Our findings thus should not be interpreted as supporting stricter regulation of financial reporting by private firms. Quite the contrary: our hypothesis is that lower earnings quality in private firms is an optimal outcome in the market for financial reporting, not a failure in supply.The following section describes the economic role of timely loss recognition (the attribute of earnings quality we measure), and its relation to conservatism and “value relevance.” The section also outlines our two principal tests of loss recognition timeliness: Basu’s (1997) method of identifying transitory loss components in income; and a test we develop that is based on the relation between accruals and cash flow from operations. Section three describes the relevant UK institutional features and develops the hypothesis that loss recognition timeliness is substantially affected by the different economic roles of financial reporting in private and public companies. Section four describes the data, section five presents the principal results, and section six describes a variety of specification tests to ensure the robustness of the results. The final two sections consider alternative explanations and summarize our conclusions.32. Timely loss recognition: hypotheses and testsThis section outlines the economic role of timely loss recognition in accounting, and its relation to conservatism and to value relevance. It then describes the two measures of loss recognition timeliness we utilize: Basu’s (1997) test for transitory time-series components in income and a new test based on the relation between accruals and cash flow from operations. 2.1 Timeliness of accounting incomeAccounting income is a barometer for evaluating financial reporting in general, because changes in balance sheet quantities flow through the income statement (assuming “clean surplus” accounting and ignoring offsetting changes such as reclassifications). Timely income-statement recognition therefore implies timely revision of all financial statement variables and all financial ratios based on them.Economic income incorporates both current-period cash flow and any revision in the present value of expected future cash flows.3 Accounting recognit ion of economic income can be thought of as occurring under two broad models: deferred and timely recognition. Deferred recognition largely ignores revisions in expectations and awaits the realization of the revised cash flows themselves. For a multi-period investment, revisions in expected cash flow for any one future period are likely to be correlated with revisions for other future periods, so deferred recognition incorporates economic gains and losses in accounting income over its entire life. Equivalently, deferred recognition generates persistent components of accounting income. Timely recognition incorporates unrealized gains or losses in income (and hence the balance sheet) on an accrued basis, for example as inventory write-downs or as restructuring or asset3 Economic income i s change in market value of equity, adjusted for dividends and capital contributions. This corresponds to the Hicks (1946) definition of income as t he maximum amount that can be consumed consistent with the maintenance of wealth. Hicks discusses alternative definitions.4impairment charges. Our tests seek to identify which recognition model is most prevalently used for economic gains and losses, and how this choice differs between public and private companies.The following subsections discuss the disproportio nate emphasis that is placed on loss recognition in accounting, relative to gain recognition, and how this asymmetry is related to conservatism and value relevance.2.2 Economic role of asymmetric timeliness in income-statement recognition of gains and lossesAccountants are reluctant to recognize (i.e., incorporate in audited financial statements) information managers possess about future cash flows when it is unobservable to external parties, and hence is unauditable (unverifiable). Thus, under the revenue recognition rules, reported income is based on actual cash flow realizations, adjusted for accruals that are derived from independently-verifiable predictors of future cash flows. One such predictor is the verified amount of accounts receivable, which is a predictor of future cash inflow, other things equal. Ignoring unverifiable information about future cash flows – such as that embodied in managers’ expectations, strategies and plans – reflects a trade-off between relevance and reliability (Financial Accounting Standards Board 1984, para. 77).Financial reporting normally modifies the revenue recognition rules by adopting a lower verification standard for information about decreases in expected future cash flows (i.e., economic losses) than for increases (i.e., economic gains).4 A primary reason for asymmetric accounting recognition is that managers have an asymmetric incentive to reveal their private information.5 Timeliness of economic loss incorporation is an important attribute of earnings4 Basu (1997, page 7), Watts (2003).5 Gilman (1939, page 232), Watts and Zimmerman (1986, page 206).5quality because it makes financial statements more useful in several contexts, for example in corporate governance and loan agreements. 6The governance effect of timely loss incorporation is due to it mitigating agency problems associated with managers’ investments decisions. If managers know ex ante that losses will be recognized during their tenure, then they are less likely to make negative-NPV investments, such as “pet” projects or “trophy” acquisitions. In contrast, if managers can defer loss recognition to periods when the reduced cash flows underlying negative NPVs are realized, then the earnings consequences of their investment decisions can be passed on to subsequent generations of managers. The ability to defer loss recognition also provides managers with an accounting-based incentive to continue operating investments with ex post negative NPVs, to avoid reported losses on sale or abandonment. These agency problems are mitigated by timely loss recognition, which reports losses around the time expectations are revised downward, irrespective of managers’ decisions to continue or abandon. Timely loss recognition therefore increases managers’ incentives to act quickly to limit economic losses, and thereby increases the efficiency of contracting between firms and managers.7The efficiency of debt agreements that utilize financial statement variables also is affected. Timely loss recognition can assist ex ante loan pricing by providing new information to lenders. It also is quicker in triggering ex post violations of covenants based on financial statement variables. This increases debt agreement efficiency by more quickly giving lenders the option to impose contractual restrictions (such as leverage, investment and dividend restrictions) on covenant violators. This applies to covenants triggered by income-statement variables such as6 Recent awareness of the importance of losses is due to Hayn (1995), Elliott and Hanna (1996), Francis, Hanna and Vincent (1996) and Collins, Maydew and Weiss (1997). Basu (1997) studies timely loss recognition, discussed below.7 An example is reported in DaimlerBenz AG Annual Report 1996 (English language version, pages 44-45), reproduced in Ball (1998). Daimler implemented US GAAP standards for calculating earnings throughout the corporation, reducing the discretion that individual business-unit managers exercised in reporting their own performance (including their capacity to hide losses), and requiring them to focus more on shareholder value.6minimum interest coverage and balance-sheet variables such as leverage ratios, because accounting losses flow from the income statement onto the balance sheet values of asset, liability and owners’ equity accounts. Consequently, timely income-statement incorporation of economic losses more quickly transfers decision rights from loss-making managers to lenders.We do not focus on timely gain recognition, for three overlapping reasons. First, we conjecture there is less demand for it. Managers have a greater incentive to disclose timely information about unrealized economic gains than unrealized losses (they can realize gains by selling), so external parties are likely to demand an offsetting asymmetry in the financial statements. For example, managers have incentives to disclose economic gains to potential lenders to obtain favorable ex ante debt pricing, thereby skewing the demand from lenders toward loss recognition in the financial statements. Further, debt agreements do not generally transfer decision rights when covenants are exceeded, only when they are violated, so there is lower ex post demand for timely gain recognition.8 In the context of corporate governance, potential agency issues arise from managers undertaking or continuing negative-NPV (not positive NPV) investments, so there is less demand from investors for timely gain recognition derived from contracting with managers. Overall, the economics of contracts involving finan cial reporting predicts asymmetry in the demand for gain and loss accounting.Second, we note that accounting rules and practice are fundamentally asymmetric. Recall that economic gains and losses involve changes in expected future cash flows, which by definition are “unrealized.” A long-standing example of asymmetric accruals is the lower of cost or market inventory rule, which recognizes unrealized economic losses arising from declines in fair values of inventory, but does not recognize unrealized gains. Accounting for gains and losses8 Beatty and Weber (2002) report that performance-pricing, under which interest rates vary inversely with accounting performance measures, is a new feature of U.S. debt contracts. While this provides incentives for timely recognition7on long-term assets also is asymmetric, as formalized in the asset impairment standards issued by several countries, including FAS 121 and 144 in the U.S. and FRS11 in the U.K. In contrast, upward revaluation has not been practiced in the U.S. since the SEC was established in 1934. In the U.K., although upward revaluation can be recognized in the balance sheet, gains from revaluation are not included in income like losses from asset impairment. In general, asymmetry is a fundamental property of accounting rules and practice.Third, the evidence is consistent with timely gain recognition not being a high priority in accounting. Basu (1997) reports that loss recognition is the prime source of timeliness in U.S. earnings. The asymmetry is difficult to reconcile with a symmetric value relevance view of accounting (Holthausen and Watts 2001). It replicates for public companies in a wide range of countries, including the U.K. (Ball, Kothari and Robin, 2000).The three reasons for not focusing on gain recognition are far from independent. To the extent that accounting standards are endogenous rather than imposed, asymmetry in demand will be reflected in standards (e.g., standards for asset impairment but not for upward revaluation), and the evidence will reveal an asymmetric response of earnings to economic gains and losses.2.3 Timely loss recognition, value relevance and conservatismTimely loss recognition is related to the concepts of value relevance and conservatism. This subsection attempts to clarify those concepts and how they relate to each other, with a view to understanding timely loss recognition, which is the attribute of reporting quality we measure.In a Basu (1997) piecewise-linear regression with fiscal-year stock return as the independent variable and current-year accounting income as the dependent variable, timely loss recognition is equivalent to a partial stock price association criterion. In this context, stock returns proxy for economic gains and losses, assuming some degree of market efficiency. The association of economic gains, we are not aware of this being practiced in the U.K. during our sample period. In any event, our8criterion is partial in that it focuses on losses, whereas a full association criterion also addresses gains. Further, the use of fiscal-year returns implies there is no gap in calendar time between successive return intervals, as is the case with short windows. Fiscal-year association tests therefore map directly into value relevance tests. In particular, timelier recognition of fiscal-year economic gains and losses (proxied by fiscal-year stock returns) implies a higher correlation between book and market values.The relation between timely loss recognition and conservatism is clouded by the existence of two related but distinct definitions o f conservatism. One definition of conservatism is an accounting bias toward reporting low book values of stockholders equity (and hence, if clean surplus accounting is being followed, low average net incomes). The second definition of conservatism is an equivalent bias conditional on firms experiencing contemporaneous economic losses. Confusion of the unconditional and conditional versions of conservatism is evident as early as Gilman (1939, page 130) and APB Statement No. 4.In the more recent literature, Watts and Zimmerman define conservatism as:9Conservatism means that the accountant should report the lowest value among possiblealternative values for assets and the highest alternative value for liabilities. Revenuesshould be recognized later rather than sooner and expenses sooner than later.This is a variant of the first definition above, in that it does not specify conditionally low equity or income, and hence does not address loss-recognition timeliness. To illustrate, under this definition a firm’s accounting is conservative if it simply delays revenue recognition by one period, or subtracts a constant from earnings every period, independent of current economic gains and losses. This type of conservatism is an asymmetric response to uncertainty: from a range of possible values, select a low value, not the expected value. It frequently is associated withhypothesis is that there is asymmetrically less demand – not no demand – for timely gain recognition.9 Watts and Zimmerman (1986, pages 205-206). See al so Watts (1993, page 1).9Germany, where under the vorsicht (prudence) principle there are unconditionally conservative practices such as charging future operating expenses against current-period income.10 Basu (1997) is an important contribution to our understanding of the conservatism concept. He defines conservatism as (page 4, emphasis added):I interpret conservatism as capturing accountants’ tendency to require a higher degree ofverification for recognizing good news than bad news in financial statements. Under my interpretation of conservatism, earnings reflects bad news more quickly than good news. Basu (pages 7-8) compares this definition – which stresses the timeliness of loss recognition – with variants of the first definition. The additional requirement of this conditional conservatism definition is that the reduction in accounting income reflects a contemporaneous economic loss. This requirement is not satisfied by expensing early, by deferring revenue, or by under-reporting income or book value on a regular basis (e.g., creating excessive provisions in all years), none of which is correlated with contemporaneous real income. The difference in definitions is most apparent in Basu’s primary research design, which studies the asymmetric incorporation of economic gains and losses (proxied by positive and negative stock returns over the fiscal year) in current-year accounting income.The distinction between conditional and unconditional asymmetry is central to understanding the role of conservatism in efficient contracting with the firm. Watts (1993, abstract page) hypothesizes that accounting conservatism “evolved from accounting’s contracting role.” He singles out “avoidance of inappropriate distributions to claim holders” to protect more senior claims (notably, debt) as “an important contracting reason for conservatism.” Watts (1993, page 5) mentions the effect of conservatism “to offset the manager’s optimism (engendered by10 See, for example, (Gray 1980). Delaying recognition or under-reporting income correspondingly reports lower book values of equity, hence lower asset values or higher liabilities.10compensation based on income).”11 Gilman (1939, page 232) explores similar effects of conservatism, and also suggests a political costs motive.The “timely loss recognition” version of conservatism provides fresh insight into its contracting role. It is difficult to see how contracting is affected by conservatism in the form of an unconditional accounting bias of known magnitude. Rational agents would simply invert the bias. For example, if book values of assets were under-reported by a known pr oportion ?, leverage covenants would increase the proportion of book value that firms could borrow by a factor of (1-?)-1, without affecting the lending rate or the circumstances under which covenants were violated. In addition, unconditional biases reduce opportunities to account in a conditionally conservative fashion (for example, writing off assets at acquisition eliminates the opportunity to impair them at the time of economic losses). Contracting-based demand for a known unconditional bias thus seems unlikely. Further, an unconditional bias of unknown magnitude introduces randomness in decisions based on financial information and can only reduce contracting efficiency.12 In contrast, the conditional form of conservatism (timely loss recognition) can improve contracting efficiency. It more quickly triggers debt covenant violations that transfer decision rights to lenders, allowing lenders to restrict managers’ actions (such as distributions, borrowing, and new investment) sooner after economic losses become apparent, thereby increasing the efficiency of debt contracting. Similarly, timely loss recognition gives managers less incentive to undertake ex ante negative-NPV projects and more incentive to abandon ex post loss-making investments quickly, thereby increasing the efficiency of compensation contracting and corporate governance.13 While unconditional conservatism seems11 Earlier, Watts and Zimmerman (1986, page 206) hypothesized a purpose of conservatism is to “offset managerial optimism (presumably encouraged by earnings-based compensation plans).”12 These points are made in the context of German vorsicht conservatism in Ball (1998).13 The role of timeliness in debt and governance is discussed in Ball, Kothari and Robin (2000, page 52), Ball (2001, pages 138-140), and Ball, Robin and Wu (2002, pages 4-5).11inefficient or at best neutral in contracting, conditional conservatism (timely loss recognition) can enhance contracting efficiency.Confusion between the unconditional and conditional versions of conservatism helps explain why conservatism is a controversial property of accounting, despite its long–standing influence on practice.14 Ambivalence is evident in APB Statement No. 4, which seemingly approves of conservatism in its unconditional version (AICPA 1970, ¶171):Conservatism. Frequently, assets and liabilities are measured in a context of significantuncertainties. Historically, managers, investors, and accountants have generally preferred that possible errors in measurement be in the direction of understatement rather thanoverstatement of net income and net assets.while combining the versions among accounting’s “characteristics and limitations” (¶35): Conservatism. The uncertainties that su rround the preparation of financial statements are reflected in a general tendency toward early recognition of unfavorable events andminimization of the amount of net assets and net income.Later, FASB Statement of Financial Accounting Concepts No. 2 defines conservatism with seeming approval as “prudent reaction to uncertainty” (FASB 1980, Glossary), which it interprets by quoting the unconditional version of APB Statement No. 4 (¶171, cited above). It then appears to cite the unconditional version disapprovingly:The convention of conservatism, which was once commonly expressed as “anticipate no profits but anticipate all losses,” developed during a time when balance sheets wereconsidered the prime (and often only) financial statement, and details of profits or otheroperating results were rarely provided … .”Ambivalence toward conservatism could reflect confusion between its unconditional and conditional forms. As argued above, in a contracting setting unconditional conservatism seems at best neutral (if the bias is known) and possibly inefficient (if the bias is unknown). In contrast, conditional conservatism involves timely loss recognition, and thereby increases the efficiency of14 Basu (1997, pages 8-9) cites evidence of conservatism in accounting as early as the fifteenth century. Gilman (1939, especially pp. 201-204) describes the controversy, which persists to this day.12。

相关文档
最新文档