market efficiency cum anomalies or baahvior finance
有效市场假说名词解释经济学
有效市场假说名词解释经济学
有效市场假说(Efficient Markets Hypothesis,简称EMH)是经济学中的一个重要理论,它认为市场是有效的,即市场价格反映了所有可获得的信息。
根据有效市场假说,市场价格是由所有可用的公开信息(包括公司公告、新闻报道、市场趋势等)和私人信息(只有某些投资者或机构持有的特定信息)决定的。
由于市场价格反映了所有可用的信息,投资者无法通过分析信息来获得超额收益。
换句话说,投资者无法通过分析信息来预测股票价格的变动,因为价格已经反映了所有可用的信息。
有效市场假说有三个主要假设:
1、投资者是理性的:他们能够理性地评估公司的价值和风险,并做出最佳的投资决策。
2、信息是完整的:所有的信息都已经被充分地披露和传播,没有隐藏的信息或内幕消息。
3、投资者可以自由进入市场:没有障碍或限制阻止投资者进入市场进行投资。
如果这三个假设成立,那么市场就是有效的,投资者无法通过分析信息来获得超额收益。
然而,在实际市场中,投资者往往存在非理性行为,信息也不一定是完整的或被充分披露的,因此有效市场假说并不总是成立。
名词解释有效市场假说
名词解释有效市场假说
有效市场假说(Efficient Markets Hypothesis,EMH)是一种金融市场的理论,它认为市场在证券价格形成中是有效的。
这一理论的主要观点是,在一个有效的市场中,证券价格能够快速且准确地反映所有可获得的信息,这包括公开信息以及非公开信息。
因此,根据有效市场假说,投资者无法通过分析这些信息来获得超额收益。
有效市场假说的三种形式包括:
1. 弱有效市场假说:该假说认为市场价格已经反映了所有过去的信息,因此投资者无法通过分析过去的价格或其它相关信息来预测未来的价格变化。
2. 半强有效市场假说:该假说认为市场价格已经反映了所有公开可获得的信息,包括公司的财务报表、新闻报道以及投资者的预期等。
因此,基于公开信息的任何投资策略都无法带来超额收益。
3. 强有效市场假说:该假说认为市场价格已经反映了所有信息,包括公开信息和内幕信息。
因此,即使拥有内幕信息的投资者也无法预测未来的价格变化。
然而,有效市场假说也面临着一些挑战和批评,例如市场是否总是有效的,以及投资者是否总是理性的等。
尽管如此,这一理论仍然在金融领域中有着广泛的应用和影响。
资产定价模型与市场有效性
资产定价模型与市场有效性资产定价模型(Asset Pricing Model)是一种用于衡量和预测金融资产价格的数学模型。
它是金融学和投资学中的重要理论框架,用于分析资产价格的形成和变动机制。
而市场有效性(Market Efficiency)则是指金融市场是否能够反映所有可用的信息,并将其及时反映在资产价格中。
本文将介绍一些常见的资产定价模型,并探讨市场有效性与资产定价模型的关系。
一、资本资产定价模型(Capital Asset Pricing Model, CAPM)资本资产定价模型是由Sharpe(1964)、Linter(1965)和Mossin (1966)等学者提出的,被广泛应用于资本市场的资产定价。
CAPM 模型认为,一个资产的预期回报和风险成正比,与市场资产组合的风险相关。
CAPM模型的数学表达如下:\[E(R_i) = R_f + \beta_i (E(R_m) - R_f)\]其中,\(E(R_i)\)是资产i的预期回报,\(R_f\)是无风险利率,\(E(R_m)\)是市场组合的预期回报,\(\beta_i\)是资产i相对于市场组合的β系数。
CAPM模型的核心是资产的β系数,反映了资产相对于市场组合的敏感性。
CAPM模型的理论基础是市场均衡和资产组合的效用最大化。
二、套利定价理论(Arbitrage Pricing Theory, APT)套利定价理论是由Ross(1976)提出的资产定价模型,用于解释资产价格的变动。
与CAPM模型不同,APT模型认为资产的价格不仅仅取决于市场风险,还受到其他因素的影响,比如通货膨胀率、利率变动、市场情绪等。
APT模型的数学表达如下:\[E(R_i) = R_f + \sum\limits_{j=1}^k \beta_{ij} f_j\]其中,\(E(R_i)\)是资产i的预期回报,\(R_f\)是无风险利率,\(\beta_{ij}\)是资产i相对于因子j的敏感性,\(f_j\)是因子j的预期回报。
第一章市场有效性
新信息和价格变动之间的异象
日历效应 例如:S&P 500指数和成分股的套利
非理性 者会犯同样的错误,但是他们在市场中会遇到理性的套利者,后者会消除前者对价格的影响。
EMH是由完全理性 者一组成月的市效场中应,市〔场呈J现a平n衡u时a所r得y到E的结ff果e。ct〕。
市场有效性〔Market Efficiency〕
市场有效性是一种信息的有效,即市场中的证券价格总是可以充 沛地表达可以获得信息变化的影响(Fama 1970) 。 新信息是证券价格变动的唯一原因〔与供求关系无关〕.
有效市场中的价格行为 价格将围绕其价值随机动摇 价格反映新信息的速度非常快 价格对新信息的反映是准确的
心理学的启发法作用:例如:给近期信息和意外信息过高的权重
EMH遇到的理论挑战
非理性交易互相独立假说的挑战〔心理学挑战〕 心理学的研究已经清楚地说明,人们并不是偶尔偏离理性,而
是经常以同样的方式偏离—理性?本性?。
个体 者受传言影响和羊群效应。
机构 者表现弱于消极 战略〔Buy and Hold),因为,自身的特性 ;出资人的影响;攀比现象—与S&P 500和其他 的攀比;管理费 用的存在,导致机构 者成为规范的噪音交易者。
Overreaction Hypothesis(ORH)—反转交易战略〔De Bondt and Thalቤተ መጻሕፍቲ ባይዱr,1985,1987〕。
市违场背有 贝效叶假斯说准的那三么个:价理利论用值根短底期:数〔据预L测o不确w定的P将/E来,r无a视t近io期〕数据和仅仅三是偶因尔结子果。模型〔Fama,
French, ) 信息集A:过去的价格信息
MARKET EFFICIENCY:市场效率
MARKET EFFICIENCYAND THEBEHAVIOUR OF SECURITIES PRICESReadings1. BKM Chapter 122. Article: "Event Studies.pdf"Please download this from the Blackboard ‘Article Folder’Further referencesFama - "Efficient Capital Markets:..." Journal of Finance May 1970 Fama - "Efficient Capital Markets: II" J. of F. December 1991The topics examined in this module are organised as follows:1. The concept of efficient capital markets2. The Efficient Market Hypothesis3. Implications for investors when markets are efficient:4. Tests of market efficiency5. Market anomalies or evidence of market inefficienciesEfficiency of financial marketsThere are two dimensions to the meaning of efficiency in markets, which can be described as(1) Operational efficiency, and(2) Functional Efficiency or informational and valuation efficiency (1) Operational efficiencyThe key elements that make a market operationally efficient are market liquidity, orderliness and low costs of trading.Liquidity means investors can dispose of their holdings quickly and without sacrificing large price discounts from prevailing market prices. Factors that contribute to market liquidity are depth, breadth and resilience.Liquidity of the market is indicated byBreadth of market (trading volumes at prevailing prices)Depth of market (volumes of buy orders below and volumes of sell orders above the prevailing price)Market breadth and depth helps to ensure resilience.Market depth means the ability of the market to absorb temporary imbalances between securities supply and demand without leading to large price changes through the trading activities of market makers. Market makers must stand ready to buy up securities when the supply of securities exceed demand, or run down their inventories of securities when demand exceeds supply. Market breadth means trading volume and the existence of adequate competition among market makers to ensure that the spread between ask and bid price is small. Resilience means the ability of the market price to recover from unusually large sell or buy orders.Market orderliness is another important aspect of an operationally efficient market which is closely related to liquidity. In an orderlymarket price changes are smooth and not erratic. It is again competitive market making activity that ensures orderliness. Absence of price manipulation is important to market orderliness. Price manipulation occurs when some participants have significant market power or when malpractices such as front running occurs.Low transaction costs provides a third contribution to operational efficiency. This means low taxes, brokerage commissions and bid-ask spreads.(2) Functional EfficiencyRelates to Informational and valuation efficiencyA market is informationally efficient if information that have a bearing on the value of securities are readily available to market participants.Informational efficiency leads to valuation efficiency. In a valuationally efficient market the prices of assets will be close to their intrinsic or fundamental values.Fama's formal definition of market efficiency - (JF 1970)A market is efficient relative to an information set ω if the priceexpectations formed on the basis of the information set ω is an unbiased predictor of the actual price subsequently realised.Let P t= price at time t ωt = the information set available to investors at time t.E P t t t ( )+1ω = expectation of future price based on today's information set.εt = the deviation of the actual price from the expected price (the prediction error)this meansεt+1= Pt+1 - E Pt t t( )+1ωIf the prediction error is unbiased then the market is efficient.E t(εt+1) = 0STANDARDS OF MARKET EFFICIENCY(The Efficient Market Hypothesis - Fama (1970) )In order to estimate and also test the degree of efficiency of a particular market, we need to define standards of efficiency as a yardstick of measurement.Eugene Fama has defined three levels of market efficiency on the basis of the amount of information that is built into (or impounded in) market prices.1. Weak Form EfficiencyOnly historical information such as the history of past price patterns are reflected or built into the current market price.The implication is that investors cannot use any knowledge of past price trends or patterns to predict future price changes and thereby develop trading strategies to earn abnormal returns.2. Semi strong Form EfficiencyA higher level of efficiency than the WFE. Assumes that all currently publicly available information is already fully reflected in market prices.The implication is that investors cannot use any publicly available information already known to the market to develop strategies to earn abnormal returns.3. Strong Form EfficiencyThe highest possible level of efficiency. Assumes that all information, whether publicly or privately held, including those with corporate insiders or market specialists, are fully reflected in market prices.The implication is that even investors with insider information cannot use their information to earn abnormal returns.Some properties associated with an efficient market(i) Price changes will result only from new information that have an effect on present and future security returns rather than on existing information.(ii) Market prices will react to new information quickly and accurately (unbiasedly)(iii) Market prices will follow (or be close to) a random walk process.P t = P t-1 +d + εtεt is an independent and identically distributed (iid) series of random errors, d is the drift in price(iv) Market prices of securities will generally reflect their true intrinsic values.Some factors driving markets to efficiency and why we can expect financial markets to be efficient(i) Laws that compel firms to disseminate important information quickly to the market(ii) An efficient and technologically advanced information network (iii) The strong competition among analysts and investors drives prices towards efficiency.Large numbers of investors all looking for abnormal profit opportunities, will by their own actions, compete away such opportunities.(iv) Investors and analysts are educated, knowledgeable and 'smart'. (v) The independence of the actions of investors.The law of large numbers will ensure that the net effect of uncorrelated trading actions of investors will result in the average prices being accurate.(vi) Do insider trading laws hinder market efficiency ?I NSIDER TRADING AND THE L AWAmendments to the Corporations Law introduced in August 1991 Who is an insider ?An insider is one who possesses 'price sensitive information which is not generally available'.An insider need not be connected to the firm under reference.What is insider trading ?Trading based on insider information or communicating insider information to another who might trade on that information is illegal. Implications for investors and the likely effectiveness of investment strategies if markets are truly efficient:(i) Predicting price changes based on historical information or past price patterns will be impossible.Therefore 'Technical' analysis based on analysing historical price patterns would be useless. Also 'market timing' strategies may be of little benefit(ii) Since market prices will adjust to new information very quickly and will accurately reflect fundamental values in generalAn active stock selection strategy based on fundamental stock analysis for identifying under and over priced stocks would not be easy.(a) Securities will plot on the security market line given that asset valuation theories such as the CAPM is correct.(b) Investors can only hope to earn a normal return from their investments. A normal return is the return commensurate to the level of risk in the investment according to the CAPM.(iii) Passive investment strategies such as investing in an index fund or other buy and hold strategies would be the most appropriate.Some alternative to the Efficient Market Hypothesis for describing the behaviour of the stock market1. The Market Overreaction Hypothesis (or the winner-loser hypothesis) Debondt and Thaler (JF 1985)A theory based on irrational investor behaviour.2. The Rational Speculative Bubbles hypothesis Blanchard and Watson (1982)A theory based on rational investor behaviour which at the same time can lead to the deviation of market prices from their fundamental values.TESTING FOR MARKET EFFICIENCY(1) Tests of weak form market efficiencyCan past returns be used to predict future returns ?(a) Testing for serial correlationEx: first order autocorrelation ρσ11112111=---=--∑T r r r r t t T t )(b) Testing filter rules for stock trading(2) Tests of semi-strong form market efficiency (Event Studies):Testing how quickly and accurately security prices respond to newly released public information ?t-1t t+1Time (days )Stock price delay ed reactionover reactionefficient respons eEvent study methodologyA test of semi strong efficiency is whether the stock price reaction to an event, taking place on day t (such as a better than anticipated earnings announcement) brings forth an immediate price reaction or whether the response lags on to day t+1 and t+2 etc.Test procedure(1) Select a sample of firms making for example, better than anticipated earnings announcements.(2) Test their price responses on day t , t+1, ......(where t = announcement date)(3) But prices will change anyway due to overall market changes (with or without the announcement).(4) Need to isolate and examine price change solely due to the announcement effect.Observed return (OR) = Return due to announcement (AR) + Normalreturn (NR)Normal return (or expected return) is the return based on the relation of the firm's return to that of the market and could be measured by applying the market model (characteristic line ).The normal return on day t for firm i based on the characteristic line is given byR it= a i+ βi R mt + e itE(R it) = a i+ βi E(R mt)AR = OR - NR= R it - E(R it)= R it- [a i+ βi E(R mt) ] = e it The abnormal returns are the regression residuals(5) Calculate the average abnormal returns (AAR)Average of the residuals for the particular day across all the sample firms(6) Calculate the cumulative average abnormal returns (CAAR) over a time interval.The sum of the average abnormal returns over several days t+1, t+2 ... etc.(7) Are the CAARs significantly different from zero ?Example: The CAAR pattern in an efficient markett-1t t+1Time (day s)Cum. abnormal return0xx xExample: In the study by Foster, Olsen and Shevlin :Stocks with large positive earnings surprises earned abnormal returns from up to 60 days prior to the earnings announcement and up to 60 days after the earnings announcement.What does this imply about market efficiency ?(3) Tests of strong form market efficiency(i) Testing whether abnormal profits are made by corporate insiders. Or test whether abnormal returns are made by outsiders following insiders' trading patterns. ie. the Jaffe study, Seyhun study(ii) Testing whether abnormal returns are made by NYSE specialists EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE OF MARKET INEFFICIENCIES OR M ARKETA NOMALIES(1) Tests of market predictability(i) Predictability of short term returnsOverall, tests of serial correlation, runs tests and filter rules find that weak form efficiency is largely validated. (Fama 1965, Fama and Blume, Lo and MacKinlay etc.)(ii) Predictability of long horizon returnsFama and French 1988 and Poterba and Summers 1988 find negative correlation in long horizon returns.These results suggest mean reversion in stock prices. But does it necessarily invalidate market efficiency ?(iii) Predictors of aggregate stock market returnsFama and French 1989 and Campbell and Shiller 1988 find that variables such as dividend yield, default yield spread can predict variation in stock market returns.(2) Cross sectional anomaliesAre the cross sectional anomalies the result of market inefficiency or the result of asset pricing anomalies ?(i) The Small firm effect (high returns of small firms especially in January)Banz 1981, Reinganum 1983 Keim 1983(ii) The low P/E strategy (high returns of low P/E stocks)Basu 1977(iii) The market to book value ratioFama and French 1992(iv) The neglected firm effectArbel and Strebel 1983, Amihud and Mendelson 1986(v) The Value Line stock ranking systemValue Line claims that the performance of stocks over the next 12 month period can be predicted if stocks are ranked in accordance with the following criteria.The rank is based on a composite of (1) relative earnings momentum (2) Earnings surprise (3) Nonparametric value position(3) Seasonal Anomalies(i) The January effect (high returns in January) (ii) The weekend effect (never sell on Mondays) French (1980)。
有效市场假说专业英语小作文
有效市场假说专业英语小作文The Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) is a theory that suggests that financial markets are "informationally efficient," meaning that asset prices reflect all available information. This theory has significant implications for investors, as it suggests that it is impossible to consistently "beat the market" by exploiting mispricings in securities.There are three forms of the EMH: weak, semi-strong, and strong. The weak form asserts that all past market prices and data are already reflected in stock prices, making it impossible to predict future price movements based on historical data. The semi-strong form states that all publicly available information is already reflected in stock prices, making it impossible to achieve abnormal returns by trading on public information. The strong form suggests that all information, public and private, is reflected in stock prices, making it impossible to achieve abnormal returns even with insider information.The implications of the EMH are significant for both individual and institutional investors. If markets areindeed efficient, then it is impossible to consistently outperform the market through stock selection or market timing. This challenges the active management approach to investing, which relies on the belief that skilled managers can outperform the market through their stock-picking and market-timing abilities.Instead, the EMH suggests that investors should adopt a passive investment strategy, such as investing in index funds or exchange-traded funds (ETFs) that track the performance of a broad market index. This approach aims to replicate the market return rather than attempt to outperform it, and it often comes with lower fees and expenses compared to actively managed funds.Despite its theoretical appeal, the EMH has been subject to criticism and debate. Critics argue that the assumption of "informational efficiency" does not hold in the real world, as there are instances of market anomalies and bubbles that cannot be explained by the EMH. Additionally, the presence of behavioral biases and irrational investor behavior suggests that markets may not always be efficient in processing information.In conclusion, the Efficient Market Hypothesis is a fundamental concept in finance that has significant implications for investment strategy. While it suggeststhat it is difficult to consistently outperform the market, it has also sparked debate and criticism regarding its assumptions and real-world applicability.有效市场假说(EMH)是一种理论,它表明金融市场是“信息效率的”,这意味着资产价格反映了所有可用信息。
市场异象与市场效率翻译版本
市场异象与市场效率G. William Schwert威廉沃特Simon School of Business, University of Rochester西蒙商学院罗彻斯特大学This paper can be downloaded from theSocial Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:/abstract=目录1 引言 (2)2 挑选出的试验规律 (2)2.1可预见的资产的差别回报 (2)2.2各时期收益的预测性的不同 (7)3 不同类型的投资者的收益 (11)3.1个人投资者 (11)3.2机构投资者 (12)3.3套利限制 (14)4 长期回报 (15)5资产定价影响 (17)6公司金融的启示 (18)7结论 (19)Anomalies and Market Efficiency市场异象与市场效率G. William SchwertUniversity of Rochester, Rochester, NY 14627and National Bureau of Economic Research(国家经济研究局)October 2002摘要实践证明,市场异象似乎与现有的资产价格行为理论并不相符。
它表明市场并不是有效的,且相关的资产价格理论也有不足之处。
这篇论文的实证表明,规模效应,价值效应,周末效应以及股息率效应在一系列研究将他们公诸于世后他们的效果变弱了或者根本不出现这些效应了。
与此同时,操作者开始实践一些学术研究中运用的投资策略。
小公司一月效应在其首次发布在学术文献上以来其作用力不断减弱,尽管有证据表明还存在这种现象。
然而,有趣的是,这种现象并不存在于那些集中投资于小型股的组合回报投资者中。
所有的这些发现使得市场异象趋于表现而非真实。
随着这些非同寻常的发现而来的恶名,诱惑了很多学者去进一步调查市场异象,并试图去解释这种现象。
Chap公共部门经济学经济学原理曼昆中英文双语实用
Immunizations 免疫Restored historic buildings 修复历史古迹Research into new technologies新技术研究开发
第14页/共45页
Negative Externalities
负外部性
Internalizing an externality involves altering incentives so that people take into account the external effects of their actions. 外部性的内在化——通过改变激励,使人们考虑他们自己行为的外部效应。
第16页/共45页
Positive Externalities 正外部性
When an externality benefits the bystanders, a positive externality exists.当外部性有利于旁观者时,就存在正外部性。The social value of the good exceeds the private value. 物品的社会价值大于私人价值。
第18页/共45页
Figure 3 Education and thntity of
Education
0
Price of
Education
第19页/共45页
图3. 教育与社会最优
教育的数量
0
教育的价格
第20页/共45页
Positive Externalities
第10页/共45页
The Market for Aluminum and Welfare Economics
铝市场和福利经济学
market effiency 假设
market effiency 假设市场效率假设在经济学中,市场效率是指市场能够快速、准确地反映出所有信息并且确保资源的有效配置。
市场效率假设认为市场参与者是理性的,他们会根据可获取的信息做出最佳的决策,从而使市场价格快速反应现有信息。
本文将探讨市场效率的理论和现实情况,并分析其对投资者和经济发展的影响。
一、市场效率理论市场效率理论主要有三种形式:弱式市场效率、半强式市场效率和强式市场效率。
1. 弱式市场效率弱式市场效率假设认为市场价格已经反映了过去的所有公开信息,因此无法通过分析历史价格和成交量来获得超额利润。
换句话说,弱式市场效率认为技术分析无法预测未来股价的走势,因为所有已知的公开信息已经被市场充分反映。
2. 半强式市场效率半强式市场效率假设认为市场价格已经反映了所有公开信息和公司基本面信息,因此无法通过股票分析或基本面分析来获得超额利润。
半强式市场效率理论认为,只有通过内部信息或非公开信息才有可能实现超额利润。
3. 强式市场效率强式市场效率假设认为市场价格已经反映了所有公开信息、公司基本面信息和内幕消息,因此不存在获得超额利润的机会。
强式市场效率理论认为,即使通过非公开信息,也无法获得长期的超额利润。
二、市场效率现实情况市场效率理论在实际市场中并不完全成立,因为市场参与者并非全都是理性的。
以下是市场效率现实情况的几个例子:1. 市场波动市场上的价格波动往往是由投资者的情绪和行为引起的,而不仅仅是基于现有的信息。
投资者可能会受到恐惧、贪婪或其他情绪的影响,从而引起市场偏离合理价值。
2. 信息不对称市场参与者之间存在着信息的不对称性,某些参与者可能掌握着更多的信息,从而导致市场价格的失真。
例如,内幕交易者可以通过非公开信息获得超额利润,违反了市场效率假设。
3. 超常规收益虽然市场效率假设认为无法获得超额利润,但仍有一些投资者通过长期的有效投资策略实现了超常规收益。
这表明市场并非完全有效,否则将没有投资者能够获得超越市场平均水平的回报。
有效市场理论详解-Efficient Markets Hypothesis
半强式有效市场 Semistrong-Form Market Efficiency
证券价格不仅能够 体现历史的价格信 息,而且反映了所 有与公司证券有关 的公开有效信息, 如公司收益,股息 红利,对公司的预 期,股票分拆,公 司间的购并活动等。
价格已充分所应出所 有已公开的有关公司 营运前景的信息。这 些信息有成交价、成 交量、盈利资料、盈 利预测值,公司管理 状况及其它公开披露 的财务信息等。假如 投资者能迅速获得这 些信息,股价应迅速
尤金·法玛(Eugene Fama)是金融经济学领 域的思想家。2009年诺贝尔经济学奖得奖热门。
有效市场理论
在一个证券市场中,如果证券价格完全反映了所 有可获得的相关信息,每一种证券的价格和其内在投 资价值相一致,并能够根据新的信息进行完全和迅速 的调整,那么就称这样的市场为有效市场(或者说该 市场达到了有效性) 。
内部信息
即只有公司内部人员才能获得的有关信息。
法玛定义了与证券 价格相关的三种类
型的信息
有效市场理论
弱式有效市场 Weak-Form Market Efficiency
证券价格能够充分 反映价格历史序列 中包含的所有信息, 如有关证券的 价格、交易量等。 如果这些历史信息 对证券价格变动都 不会产生任何影响, 则意味着证券市场
有效市场理论
Efficient Markets Hypothesis
LOGO
Contents
1
尤金·法玛 中美等国各处于哪种有效市场?
尤金·法玛
Eugene Fama
有效市场理论最早由美国经济学家萨缪尔森 和尤金·法玛于1965年正式提出。1970年法玛 在总结前人研究成果的基础上,在其论文《有效 资本市场:对理论和实证工作的评价》中对有效 市场理论进行了全面阐述 。尤金·法玛被喻为 “效率市场理论之父”。
2021年~2022年 ACCA F9复习精华笔记(三)
F9复习笔记(三)Part F BusinessValuation1.Capitalmarket efficiency1.1Marketefficiency hypothesis1)operational efficiency2)allocative efficiency3)information processing efficiency1.2Differentforms of market efficiency1)The weak formHistorical information, random2)The semi-strong formHistorical and all publicly availableinformation 3)the strong formAll available information, whether public orprivate 1.3Technicaland fundamental analysis1)Technical analysisPredict future share price and share pricetrend, clear implying that a relation between past and future prices2)Fundamental analysisUse public information to calculate afundamental value and then offers investment advice by comparing thefundamental value with the current market price1.4Anomaliesin the behavior of share price1)the calendar effect2)size anomalies (market capitalization) (小公司成长空间大)3)value effects4)noise trader噪音交易者2.Valuationof business2.1When stock market is efficientMarket capitalization=market price of share*no.of share2.2Whenstock market is not efficient五种方法!方法一:Net asset valuation (NAV) 净资产(equity)估值法E=book value of net asset±adjustment(不含优先股)方法二:Price/Earning(P/E) ratio method市盈率法Value of E=P/E ratio * (profit after tax+ constantsynergy after tax)Value of share=P/E ratio * EPS方法三:Earning yield 收益率法Earning yield=EPS/share priceShare price=EPS/earning yield方法四:The dividend valuation model 股利定价模型Dividend no growth: E=D0/KeDividend constant growth: E=D0(1+g)/(Ke-g)方法五:Free cash flow (FCF) 净现金流注意要减去债权人的钱Value of equity=corporate value-market value of debtDiscount rate (use target company’sWACC) corporatevalue=FCF discount @WACCThe FCF is the best valuation model because it is based on the future cash flowand the risk associated with the cash flow。
有效市场假说
有效市场假说有效市场假说(Efficient Market Hypothesis,EMH)是指市场上所有可得到的信息都充分地反映在了市场价格中,因此市场价格能够准确地反映资产的价值,投资者无法通过分析信息来获得超额的投资收益。
有效市场假说的理论依据之一是信息效率,即市场上的信息是充分和准确的。
有效市场假说认为,投资者都是理性的,他们会充分利用所有的可得到的信息,并将其纳入投资决策中。
如果市场上有任何未被充分利用的信息,投资者就会利用这些信息实施交易,进而将市场价格调整到正确的水平。
因此,市场价格可以被视为资产的真实价值。
有效市场假说分为三种形式:弱式有效市场假说、半强式有效市场假说和强式有效市场假说。
弱式有效市场假说认为市场价格反映了过去的所有历史信息,因此投资者无法通过分析历史价格来获得超额收益。
弱式有效市场假说的理论依据是,投资者无法通过分析过去的价格模式来预测未来的价格走势,因为过去的价格模式并不能提供任何对未来价格走势的有价值的信息。
半强式有效市场假说认为市场价格不仅反映了历史信息,还反映了所有公共信息。
任何公共信息都会被及时反映在市场价格中,投资者无法通过分析公共信息来获得超额收益。
半强式有效市场假说的理论依据是,公共信息是每个人都可以获得的,因此如果某个人能够通过分析公共信息来获得超额收益,其他投资者就会效仿,市场价格就会立即调整到正确的水平。
强式有效市场假说认为市场价格反映了所有的信息,包括公共信息和非公共信息(内幕信息)。
投资者无法通过分析任何信息来获得超额收益,即使是内幕信息也不能提供超额收益的机会。
强式有效市场假说的理论依据是,内幕信息是非法获取的,所有投资者都无法获得这些信息,因此无法利用内幕信息来获得超额收益。
有效市场假说对投资者的启示是,无论是个人投资者还是机构投资者,在实践中都很难获得超额收益。
因此,投资者应当注重风险管理,选择适合自己风险偏好的投资组合,而不是试图通过分析信息来获得超额收益。
金融学中的市场效率假说分析
金融学中的市场效率假说分析金融市场是一个高度复杂且充满不确定性的系统。
市场效率假说(Efficient Market Hypothesis,EMH)是金融学中的一个重要理论,它认为金融市场是高效的,即市场上的价格充分反映了所有可用的信息,投资者无法获得超过市场平均收益率的利润。
本文将就市场效率假说的基本原理、实证研究以及重要争议进行分析和讨论。
一、市场效率假说的基本原理市场效率假说的核心观点是,金融市场上的资产价格已经反映了全部可获取的信息,投资者无法利用已知信息来获得超过市场平均收益率的利润。
根据市场效率假说,如果市场是弱有效的,即当前价格能够充分反映历史价格和交易量等信息,那么投资者无法通过技术分析来获取持续的超额收益。
如果市场是半强有效的,即价格不仅反映历史数据,还反映了公开信息,那么投资者也无法通过基本分析来获得超过市场平均水平的投资回报。
只有市场是强有效的,即价格能够及时反映全部信息,投资者无法通过任何形式的信息来获得超额收益。
二、市场效率假说的实证研究市场效率假说自从提出以来,引起了广泛的研究和争议。
许多关于市场效率的实证研究通过检验股票市场的随机行走或者股价预测模型中的各种信息变量是否有效,来测试市场是否是弱有效的。
许多研究发现,股票价格确实是随机游走的,对于普通投资者,很难通过技术分析获得超额收益。
然而,也有一些研究发现了某些非随机特征,表明市场可能并不完全弱有效。
例如,研究发现一些市场现象和行为异常,如超额波动性(excess volatility)、股票的长期偏离均衡价格(long-run deviations)、动量效应(momentum effect)等,这些异常似乎暗示了市场并非完全弱有效。
三、市场效率假说的重要争议市场效率假说并非没有争议,学术界存在多种观点。
其中之一是反对派认为市场并不是完全弱有效的,即投资者可以利用一些公开信息来获得超额收益,例如分析师的研究报告、专业投资者的操盘策略等。
The Efficient Market Hypothesis
11-10
Types of Stock Analysis
• Fundamental Analysis - using economic and accounting information to predict stock prices
CHAPTER 11
The Efficient Market Hypothesis
McGraw-Hill/Irwin
INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS
Copyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS
11-7
EMH and Competition
• Information: The most prect – Strong competition assures prices reflect information. – Information-gathering is motivated by desire for higher investment returns. – The marginal return on research activity may be so small that only managers of the largest portfolios will find them worth pursuing.
INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS
11-16
Are Markets Efficient?
资本市场效率word版
第三专题资本市场效率一.论文报告论文名称:“ANOMALIES AND MARKET EFFICIENCY”(异常现象和市场效率)作者:G.William Schwert摘自:Handbook of the Economics of Finance;NBER working paper二.论文主题:本文主要考察资本市场的异常现象,包括规模效应、价值效应、周末效应、股息效应以及年初效应,个人投资者和机构投资者的行为效应。
讨论这些异常现象所表达资本市场的效率方面的意义,以及这些异常现象对公司金融的指导意义三.问题的研究方法:采用比较研究方法,为了研究异常现象产生的原因,采用了在该现象的学术研究文献发表之日以后的数据,重新研究该异常现象,并且与以前的研究进行比较,从而发现是否存在变化,并且解释原因。
四.论文结构:1.分为7个小节,第一节:引言和本主题的研究动态。
第二节:讨论资产收益的规律性,即异常现象,包括规模效应、book-to-market效应、动量效应和股息收入效应。
第三节:讨论个人投资者和机构投资者的投资行为,这部分内容属于行为金融学的内容。
第四节:讨论文献中研究异常现象中所采用度量方法的问题。
第五节:讨论这些异常现象,对资产定价理论的意义。
第六节:异常现象对公司金融(公司财务)的意义。
第七节:总结。
2.根据结构,大致可以将文章分为四部分:1)引言和研究动态。
2)研究文献中提到的异常现象,并且利用相互独立的数据(采用论文发表后所观察到的数据)重新研究,发现结论有了显著的不同。
3)解释异常现象和资本市场效率、资产定价理论以及公司金融应用方面的关系。
也就是探讨异常现象的意义,以及异常现象发生变化的意义。
4)总结五.论文主要内容:1.异常现象:和资产定价模型理论不一致的实证结论,就称为异常现象。
2.存在异常现象的意义:1)市场无效(存在套利机会)。
2)资产定价模型不充分。
3.存在异常现象的原因:1)市场微观结构产生的造成市场无效。
是,首相(Yes,PrimeMinister)经典对白——如何跟领导拐弯抹角
是,⾸相(Yes,PrimeMinister)经典对⽩——如何跟领导拐弯抹⾓使⽤复杂、抽象的英语表达也许是为了使⽂体更加正式,但有时故意把简单的事情说得复杂可能是“别有⽬的”。
试举英剧《是,⾸相》当中的⼀个⽚段为例——对话背景: 欧洲深受债务危机之困,各国⾸脑举⾏会议商议出路,但会议⼀直没有实质性进展。
⾸相Jim不仅被媒体指责毫⽆作为,还被党内同僚觊觎⾸相之位,乌纱帽朝不保⼣。
秘书Humphrey私下⾥与Kumranistan(经查是虚构的国家)外交⼤⾂达成⼝头协议,Kumranistan⼤⾂表⽰愿意向欧洲提供⼗万亿贷款,只要之后欧洲各国向Kumranistan那⾥购买⽯油。
当Humphrey告诉Jim这个“好消息”时,Jim⾮常开⼼:他相信任何问题都将迎刃⽽解,甚⾄开始幻想⾃⼰的名字登上报纸头条、载⼊史册的伟⼤时刻。
然⽽,Humphrey 没有告诉⾸相,这个协议有个“隐含条件”——贷款必须经过ECB之⼿,这意味着英国如果不加⼊欧元区,就根本分不到贷款。
当然,英国⾸相是绝对不会同意英国加⼊欧元区的,秘书⾃然也很清楚这⼀点,所以刻意隐瞒了“隐含条件”。
⽽⾸相的另⼀得⼒助⼿发现了不对劲,私下⾥提醒⾸相可能有“诈”。
⾸相也开始担⼼被⼈挖了个“坑”,于是找来秘书,质问之。
(PM =Prime Minister; H=Humphrey)PM: This Kumranistan loan is all good news, isn’t it?H: Oh, tremendous news!PM: There are no hidden snags, you know? Terms and conditions? Penalty clauses? Tough guarantees?H: Oh, no, nothing like that. Standard agreement.PM: Great! Just an ordinary treasury loan, as far as we’re concerned?H: In a sense, yes.PM: In a sense? (frowning)H: Well, in due course, following agreed procedures, after certain formalities.PM: But the money goes straight to the Treasury (国库)?H: Yes, it goes to the Treasure, of course.PM: STRAIGHT to the Treasury?H: Well, broadly speaking, yes. More or less.PM: Broadly speaking? How would you describe it if you were narrowly speaking?Does it have to go through the European Central Bank?H: Prime Minister, we get the money, that is what matters.PM: Let me put this another way—will this loan be in euros?H: Prime Minister, I do urge you not to clutter your mind with procedural detail and monetary trivia.PM: Humphrey! In words of one syllable, is this plan dependent on our abandoning sterling (英国货币) and joining the euro? H: Well, “dependent” has three syllables, and “a-ban-don-ing” has four. (Fake-smiling “HA HA”)…PM: Humphrey! Answer my question!H: Alright, Prime Minister. You’ve asked a straight question, and I’ll give you a straight answer, which, however, clearly depends on its context. In the course of all financial negotiations, certain provisos have to be pre-cogitated and preconditioned; various caveats have to be postulated, designated, investigated and specified, and a number of considerations have to be unequivocally determined, acknowledged, and indeed, sometimes even conceded, so that we can facilitate the finalization of preliminary plans to create an epistemological basis for all parties to proceed towards a mutually beneficial consummation, which will acknowledge and safeguard the vital interests of all the participants without jeopardizing in any material way the underlying collective benefits, ultimately accruing to the signatories, or leaving unresolved any anomalies or irregularities which could precipitate operational uncertainty down the line, so that there will be a presumedmodicum of iron-clad reciprocity, which, in the great scheme of things, will be to everyone’s advantage. (Applause from the audience...)PM: Did that mean yes or no?H: Don’t you think that yes and no are r ather broad and unspecific in their application?PM: No!I want a clear, unambiguous answer!H: Certainly. What was the question again?PM: Is joining the euro a condition of getting the loan?H: Well, in the sense that, if agreement, at the end of the day…PM: Humphrey! I repeat—Is joining the euro a condition of getting the loan?H: Yes, Prime Minister.(The End)Source: Yes, Prime Minister (2013), Season 1 Episode 1, 26’15’’-29’20’’.。
- 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
- 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
- 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。
Homo Oeconomicus 24(1): 81–93 (2007)www.accedoverlag.de Market Efficiency cum Anomalies,or Behavioral Finance?George M. FrankfurterLloyd F. Collette professor Emeritus at Louisiana State University, Baton Rouge, USA (eMail: pitypalaty@)Abstract The efficient markets hypothesis of Fama and the capital asset pricing model of Sharpe constitute the paradigm of what is often called modern finance. Although early, joint tests of both the hypothesis and the model showed the ‘signs’ of existence, serious doubts started to surface with the large-scale discovery of ‘effects,’ for which neither the former nor the latter could account. For a long time such effects were noted but largely dismissed as anomalies; deviations or depar-tures from the norm. It was not until prospect theory of Kahneman and Tversky found its way to the financial economics literature that an alternative logic of in-vestors’ behavior has been seriously contemplated and tested. This literature is re-ferred to by its practitioners as behavioral finance. Yet, the aficionados of modern finance call the empirical findings of behavioral finance as another set of anoma-lies. This paper is about the differences between modern and behavioral finance, and how the proponents of the former try to perpetuate their theory by referring to the latter as anomalies.Keywords market efficiency, behavioural finance, financial economics paradigm, modern financeWe have first raised a dust then complain we cannot see.— Bishop Bradley, Principles of Human Knowledge.1.IntroductionFama’s ‘Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work’ saw the light of publication (Fama, 1970) in 1970. The paper re-defined his earlier allusion to capital markets’ efficiency (Fama, 1965) and simply argued that in an efficient market prices reflect all what there is to know about a capital asset. Later, Fama’s efficient market hypothesis [EMH, subsequently] was ‘endowed’ with three distinct forms of ‘infor-© 2007 Accedo Verlagsgesellschaft, München.ISBN 3-89265-064-0 ISSN 0943-018082 Homo Oeconomicus 24(1) mational efficiency,’ namely, the weak, the semi-strong, and the strong forms.1Although the exact origins of these three forms are not explicitly known, or traceable, it is generally held that:•the weak form implies a random walk of some form (part of Fama’s 1965 definition of efficiency), and that one cannot take advantage of the knowledge of historical price movements,•the semi-strong form implies that prices at any given time incorporate all publicly available information, and•the strong form implies that prices at any given time incorporate all in-formation, whether public or private.The EMH revolutionized beliefs about the pricing and the operation of capital markets, because it was in line with an ideology that markets, whether capital or otherwise, know best. Accordingly, one must conclude that as a social policy, the best government can do is not to interfere with such operation because it would make something which is efficient (good) inefficient (the opposite of good), to be slighted and avoided.Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965), and Black (1972) conjured up a statisti-cally testable model that described the pricing mechanism of capital assets. It should be remembered, thought, that both the EMH of Fama and the capital asset pricing model [CAPM, subsequently] of Sharpe described the operation and the characteristics of capital markets. That is, markets not just for stocks but all capital assets. Regardless, all subsequent tests of both the model and the hypothesis were done on a universe, some times even limited universe, of common stocks.In this paper I am discussing how doubts about both the model and the hypothesis surfaced, how the believers in the model have been trying to fight off efforts to replace them, and what language is being used to ac-complish the latter task.I will also offer my beliefs regarding the emergence of a possible alter-native paradigm and its future.2.Here come the effetsThe EMH and CAPM were internally consistent and connected in the sense that the latter provided a means for testing the former. This syn-thesis opened a door for empirical validation of both the hypothesis and1 There are also two other dimensions of efficiency, namely, allocational efficiency and liquidity. In the interest of the discussion here these other forms can be disregarded.G.M Frankfurter: Market Efficiency cum Anomolies 83 the pricing model. Through this door, or rather floodgate, thousands ofresearch papers marched to accept or reject the validity of either or boththe hypothesis and the model. A very large number of these empiricalstudies found that the theory couldn’t be rejected, based on the data thatwere available at the time.2Yet, after a while numerous studies have found results that showed theexistence of ‘effects’ that the CAPM could not explain or were consistentwith the EMH (that all relevant information is reflected in the price). Thelist of the ‘effects’ is rather large, but some at least must be mentioned here.Banz (1981) and Rienganum (1981) found evidence that the CAPMunderstates cross-sectional average returns of NYSE and AMEX listedfirms with low market values of equity and overstates those of firms withhigh market values of equity. This well-known phenomenon is now gen-erally referred to in the literature as the Small Firm Effect (SFE).Lamoureux and Sanger (1989) find the SFE in NASDAQ traded firms andconclude that the SFE cannot be attributed to market structure differencesbetween the NYSE/AMEX and the NASDAQ. Symmetrically, they con-clude that these markets are not different one from the other. After the2000 melt-down of the dotcoms the Lamoureux and Sanger (ibid.) find-ings were seriously questioned.Nevertheless, evidence contrary to the SFE also exists. Keim (1983) andBrown, Kleidon and Marsh (1983) find instability and reversals in the firmsize anomaly for NYSE/AMEX listed firms. Their results indicate thatfactors other than the relation between a stock's return and overall marketreturns need to be incorporated in modeling firm's expected returns.Other empirical evidence supports the view that the relation between riskand stock returns is captured by some combination of firm specific andmarket specific information.Basu (1983) finds E/P (earning/price) and firm size to be constituents ofaverage returns for NYSE/AMEX listed firms. Nonetheless, Basu also findsbeta, as extracted from the CAPM, to be positively related to returns,indicating that an overall market factor is a component of expected re-turns. In addition to firm size and beta, Bhandari (1988) documents thatleverage, as measured by the total debt-to-equity ratio, is instrumental inexplaining expected stock returns of NYSE/AMEX firms. Chan and Chen(1991) attribute the SFE to the fact that portfolios of small NYSE firmscontain a large proportion of marginal, financially distressed firms. Theyargue that high leverage and reduced dividends explain abnormal returns32 For an extensive list of references of this literature please see Frankfurter (2001).3 The term ‘abnormal return’ comes from the voluminous literature of event studies. Defacto, abnormal returns are nothing else but the arbitrary compilation of error terms from a84 Homo Oeconomicus 24(1) associated with portfolios of small firms.Fama and French (1992) analyze both NYSE/AMEX and NASDAQ traded firms and find that market capitalization and the ratio of the book value of equity to the market value of equity better explain cross-sectional average stock returns than beta, leverage and E/P. They suggest that firm size and the book-to-market equity ratio are useful for extracting market information about risk and expected returns, because they are better proxies of risk. Basu (1983) and Bhandari (1988) also discredit the impor-tance of beta in the explanation of market returns, just as Fama and French (1992) do later.Amihud and Mendelson (1986) develop and empirically verify a ‘liquidity hypothesis’ under which asset returns are positively related to the relative bid-ask spread, which in turn are negatively related to investor liquidity needs. Furthermore, they find the SFE to be a consequence of the spread effect, with firm size functioning as a proxy for liquidity. The sig-nificance of the bid-ask spread and the inconsequence of size reported by Amihud and Mendelson (1989) gives rise to the postulate that excess re-turns of small firms is an illiquidity premium caused by either the lack of investors' interest and/or paucity of publicly available information.Merton (1987) develops a multi-period CAPM that rests upon the as-sumption that market participants require a premium for investing in firms for which little public information is available. This notion, later, is parlayed into the neglect effect, whereas firms’ returns which are not fol-lowed at all, or by a small number of analysts are inferior of those firms that are followed by a large number of analystsInvestor interest and publicly available information may also vary ac-cording to the market in which a firm's stock is traded. Studies of the early 1990’s document significantly higher returns for NYSE/AMEX listed firms than NASDAQ firms (in contrast to Lamoureux and Sanger, 1989, who find no difference between the two markets). One must not wonder, based on 1999’s record braking performance of the NASDAQ how well this, as well as all other, empiricism stands up to time. This is so, because the NASDAQ practically crashed and burned in 2000 barely recovering since.Reinganum (1991) finds the NASDAQ to be more liquid than the NYSE for small firms. Reinganum ascribes the higher return on NYSE small firms to a liquidity premium. Loughran (1993) attributes the differ-ence between firm's returns on the NYSE and the NASDAQ to the poor performance of recent Initial Public Offerings [IPO’s, subsequently] on the NASDAQ, while Fama, French, Booth and Sinquefield (1993) attribute the difference between NYSE/AMEX and NASDAQ traded stocks to higher simple linear regression often called the market model.G.M Frankfurter: Market Efficiency cum Anomolies 85 financial distress for NYSE firms. Overall, these results indicate that theremight be an exchange affect that has to be controlled when studying firmspecific returns.The findings of these effects, as well as other, more exotic effects, suchas the end-of-the-month, – year, Yom Kippur, neglected stocks, etc.,effects that showed the lack of validity of Sharpe’s CAPM were christenedanomalies, a diminutive term that implied a tolerable aberration from aruling belief system. And because according to Fama (1998) the CAPMand the EMH are inseparably linked, the existence of these anomalies, andothers I have not mentioned, are not sufficient to either refute the hy-pothesis or the model.3.… or behavioral financeTwo wrongs don’t make one right, but they make a good excuse.— Thomas SzaszSerious questioning of modern finance as a paradigm started with the im-portation of prospect theory of Kahneman and Tversky (1979) andTversky and Kahneman (1990) into studies of asset pricing. Prospect the-ory is just one alternative to the expected utility maxim (EUM, subse-quently), based on the rationale and untold numbers of experimentalpsychology studies, that the Von Neuman and Morgenstern (1967) [VM,subsequently] axioms upon which EUM builds do not hold. I am espe-cially nonplussed for two reasons:Why only prospect theory, and not other alternative theories of deci-sion making? andHow financial economics was made immune to the rich literature ofother alternatives?Being conspiracy theorists I may be able to answer the second question.An elite who professionally benefited from a positivist way of thinkingkept out the literature critical to the EUM, starting with Allias Paradox(1952), continuing with Rubinstein’s (1988) ‘Similarity,’ and half a dozenother alternative paradigms, not germane to the current issue. I must ad-mit, however, that I have no answer to the first question.3.1OverreactionThe precursor to the over/under –reaction hypothesis of DeBondt andThaler (1985, 1987) is Basu (1978) who reports superior returns of low P/Estocks and inferior returns of high P/E stocks. Basu interprets this findingas inappropriate response to information inconsistent with the EMH that86 Homo Oeconomicus 24(1) is later corrected.Dreman (1979) builds his argument on psychological factors. Accord-ingly, he hypothesizes that investors react to events in a fashion that con-sistently overvalue the prospects of ‘best’ investments and undervalue those they consider the ‘worst.’ Earlier others, (Hickman; 1958, and Atkinson; 1967) find similar reactions to disappointing reports.But the real boost to the overreaction hypothesis comes from DeBondt and Thaler (1985, 1987), as mentioned earlier. Dreman and Berry (1995) summarize the hypothesis’ six predictions:•For long periods ‘best’ stocks underperform while ‘worst’ stocks out-perform the market.•Positive surprises boost ‘worst’ stock prices significantly more than they do the same for ‘best’ stocks.•Negative surprises depress ‘best’ stock prices much more than they do for ‘worst’ stocks.•There are two distinct categories of surprises: event triggers (positive surprises on ‘worst’ stocks, and negative surprises on ‘best’), and re-inforcing events (negative surprises on ‘worst’ stocks and positive sur-prises on ‘best’). Event-triggers result in much larger price movements than do reinforcing events.•The differences will be significant only in the extreme quintiles, with a minimal impact on the 60% of stocks in the middle.•Overreaction occurs before the announcement of earnings or other sur-prises. A correction of the previous overreaction occurs after the sur-prise. ‘Best’ stocks move lower relative to the market, while ‘worst’ stocks move higher, for a relatively long time following a surprise.Dreman and Berry (1995) claim that all six predictions of overreaction show statistical significance.Other overreaction evidence is found in Fama and French (1992), Lakonishok, Shleifer and Vishny (1994), and Loughran and Ritter (1996). Much research of overreaction is in the IPO’s literature of which I care to mention here Loughran and Ritter (1995). In a nutshell, several studies showed the long term performance of IPO’s is below what the market ex-pects it to be at the time of the initial offering. Is it possible that the market is a slow or disadvantaged learner?3.2UnderreactionA number of event studies (yet again!) show evidence of underreaction, just to balance the inefficiency of the market. Obviously, underreaction is the instance where the market, supposedly informationally efficient, doesG.M Frankfurter: Market Efficiency cum Anomolies 87 not react to information in time, or does react in an insufficient manner:too little, too late. Bernard and Thomas (1990) and Abarbanell andBernard (1992) show that financial analysts underreact to earnings an-nouncements, either over or under estimating quarterly earnings afterpositive (negative) surprises. Michaely, Thaler and Womack (1995), findprice responses to dividend cuts and/or initiations to continue for an ex-cessively and irrationally long time. Ikenberry, Lakonishok and Vermaelen(1995) contend that investors underreact to firms’ share repurchases.3.3Contrarians at the gateAll the empirical evidence of the behavioral finance literature gave rise toan investment strategy that systematically exploits the fact that the marketis not as efficient as the high priest and their sycophants, toadies andminions of the EMH want everyone to believe. Perhaps the best-qualifiedspokesperson of the contrarians is David Dreman who not only wrote twobooks on the subject (1979, 1998), but at one time also actively managed$8 billion in assets. Dreman and others believe that they can systematicallyoutperform the market by taking advantage of psychological factors thatmany of the studies I mentioned so far show to exist, and because of whichthe market cannot be efficient. For the contrarians whether the market isefficient or not is an important, yet only a secondary issue. What counts isbeating the market, consistently, a strategy tantamount to not to invest inthe market as a whole, or mimic a popular index.3.4SummaryThe trouble with behavioral finance at its present stage of existence, and asa viable alternative to the EMH, is threefold.•It does not amount to a comprehensive methodology, a clear combina-tion of ontology (what is to be known), and epistemology (how it is tobe known).•Its empirical evidence is almost exclusively event-studies, which I criti-cized elsewhere (Frankfurter and McGoun, 1995), and about whichperhaps the words of the greatest living American philosopher, YogiBerra sound true: I believe it when I believe it.•Its structure, with the exception of some basic assumptions regardinginvestors’ behavior, is the same as the EMH and its aim is the exclusivediscreditation of the EMH. This gives the home court advantage to theEMH, because behavioral finance’s findings can be and often are re-buked by the proponents of the EMH on technical grounds.88 Homo Oeconomicus 24(1)Perhaps, one of these days researchers in finance will wake up and realize that whether markets are efficient or not is not the issue. The issue is to learn more about the decision processes of real investors and find a way to categorize such behavior so later a comprehensive theory could be developed on this foundation.4.Why then anomolies?Out of timber so crooked as that from which man is made,nothing entirely straight can be carved.— Immanuel Kant First, Ball (1996), then Fama (1998) attack behavioral finance, the former with vehemence, and the latter with cunning. Ball (1996) argues that one has to stick with the EMH because (1) we don’t have anything better, (2) it sufficed in the past, and (3) it is now a matter of belief. Certainly, alterna-tives to the EMH are few. Ball can think of only one, which he calls ‘be-havioral finance,’ (ibid., p. 10) referring, principally, to the works of DeBondt and Thaler (1985, 1987). Ball (ibid., pp. 10-11) dismisses this ‘’behavioral’ finance’ on the grounds that:•Investors’ myopia implied by the DeBondt and Thaler work would be ‘grossly inconsistent’ with the notion of competitive markets. (How could one possibly doubt that they are competitive?)•Behavioral finance is also replete with its own anomalies. (Let he who is without sin cast the first stone.)•The claim that ‘efficient marketists’ suppressed evidence contrary to their beliefs is at variance with Ball’s own views and with the fact that ina co-authored work with Brown (Ball and Brown, 1968) they discov-ered ‘post-earnings-announcement ‘drift’ in prices.’ (We have been doing business in the same location for over 40 years. Doesn’t conti-nuity count for something?) (See, Frankfurter and McGoun, 1999).There is no question that the Ball’s second point is well taken. There is no theoretical model that at one point or another in its life-cycle would not have been burdened with exceptions to its rules, or aberrations from its dictum. The first point, however, is wishful thinking, the product of an ideology to which Ball and the Chicago/Rochester School subscribe, and the last point is meaningless.Fama’s (1998) dismissal of ‘behavioral finance’ is far more cleft and crafty. Fama aims with the careful screening of 20 or so papers, mostly from the domain of ‘post-event studies,’ first, to discredit empirical evi-G.M Frankfurter: Market Efficiency cum Anomolies 89 dence. Then, second, that random and conflicting evidence is proof of theexistence of the EMH. Thirdly, that event studies are not merely a method,but a methodology. And lastly, making behavioral finance synonymouswith anomalies.Perhaps this is the most important objective of Fama, because as long aseverything else is just an anomaly the EMH is, practically, irreplaceable.4In essence, when one lumps behavioral finance together with the ‘effects’literature and one calls it anomalies, one creates an unshakable and im-penetrable dogma.5.A paradigm shift?One can live in the shadow of an idea without grasping Elizabeth BowenIs it opportune then to talk about a drastic change of course, what is usuallycalled in the natural sciences, a paradigm shift? An appropriate definition ofparadigm shift is by Colin Bruce.Science is generally supposed to proceed in patient incremental steps. Butjust a few times in the history of science an experiment has produced a result soparadoxical, so difficult to explain in terms of the expected order, that the wholeframework of current assumptions about the world has to be abandoned in fa-vor of a new more subtle picture (Bruce 1998).Accepting Bruce’s definition, it is clear that behavioral finance is noparadigm yet, much less is it a shift. This is so, because when and if onepeels away the surface claim of ‘behavioral’ it is no more than traditional(modern) finance with different assumptions. Although its assumptionsmore realistically describe individual behavior and investment psychologythan modern finance this does not make behavioral finance a paradigm.The objectives, methods and data of research are exactly the same as inmodern finance.Behavioral finance then is neither a new paradigm, nor is it a differentmethodology. Yet, it is call for a cause célèbre. It has the potential to be-come one, if instead of attacking it researchers would be encouraged to de-velop it further, quite possibly importing the methods and proceduresused in related social sciences.There is a lot to learn from psychology, sociology, and anthropology.This learning cannot and will not take place if researchers are not allowedto publish their work, or being warned off because of their way of inquiry.4 Here I should remind the reader that Fama and French (1992) conclude that ‘β has nopredictive power,’ the ultimate failure of a positive model. Yet Fama (1998) makes the pointthat the CAPM and the EMH are inseparably intertwined.90 Homo Oeconomicus 24(1) It would be no one’s loss and perhaps everybody’s benefit if the chance were given to behavioral finance to be fully developed. The same elite that are trying hard to forestall such development should be the first one to recognize this simple truth, if for nothing else but in the name of academic honesty.There are a few positive developments, nevertheless, that may ring in a promising future for behavioral finance. First, there is the fact that the Nobel Prize for economics in 2001 and 2002 went mostly to scholars who were instrumental in creating behavioral economics. As a consequence, behavioral economics, after 20 odd years being in the making, gained le-gitimacy as a subfield. Because financial economics is closely tied to trends in economics, it is reasonable to surmise that behavioral finance will gain legitimacy, as well.A related supporting signal is the existence of a journal that carries the name: The Journal of Behavioral Finance. This is the journal that formerly was known as The Journal of Psychology and Financial Markets. The name change may look mere symbolism, yet there is much more to it than just a new name for an old icon. The fact that the journal is named after a pos-sible subfield of finance is an invitation for research and work that previ-ously couldn’t find a place in the mainstream journals of finance. That is, work that otherwise could survive the scrutiny of academic standards could not be published, because the referees and the political inclination of the journals were not in tune with the findings.In the words of Ludwig Wittgenstein ‘Knowledge is in the end based on acknowledgment.’ Accordingly, research is done first and foremost to be recognized. To be recognized the researcher needs an outlet. This new journal can very well become such an outlet, inspiring more work in the subfield.And lest not forget that it is also tenure and promotion that goes to-gether with recognition. Faculty, especially, young and more productive faculty will not start work where the possibility of publication, even as just a promise, does not exist.Finally, being the eternal optimist by nature, I most sincerely believe that a reality retardant theory cannot survive ad infinitum, and a new gen-eration of academics will emerge from the failures of the old elite. ReferencesAbarbanell, J. S., and Bernard V. L. (1992) Tests of Analyst’s Overreaction / Under-reaction to Earnings Information as an Explanation for Anomalous Stock Price Behavior, Journal of Finance 47: 1181–1207.Allais M. (1952) Fondoments d’une théorie positive des choix comportant un risque at critique des postulats at axiomes de l’ecole américaine. Mémoire présente auG.M Frankfurter: Market Efficiency cum Anomolies 91Colloque International sur le risque. Centre National de la Reserche Scienti-fique. Paris.Amihud, Y. and Mendelson, H. (1986) Asset Pricing and the Bid-Asked Spread,Journal of Financial Economics, 15: 223–249.Amihud, Y., and H. Mendelson (1989) The Effects of Beta, Bid-Asked Spread, Re-sidual Risk and Size Upon Stock Returns, Journal of Finance 44: 9–486.Atkinson, Th. R.,(1967) Trends in Corporate Bond Quality. NBER, Columbia Uni-versity Press.Ball, R. (1996) The Theory of Stock Market Efficiency: Accomplishments andLimitations, Journal of Financial Education 22: 1–13.Bernard, V. L., and Thomas, J.K. (1990) Evidence that Stock Prices Do Not FullyReflect the Implications of Current Earnings for Future Earnings, Journal of Ac-counting and Economics 13: 305–340.Bhandari, L. C. (1988) Debt/Equity Ratio and Expected Common Stock Returns:Empirical Evidence, Journal of Finance 43: 507–528.Basu, S. (1978) The Effect of Earnings Yield on Assessments of the Associationbetween Annual Accounting Income Numbers and Security Prices, The Ac-counting Review 53: 599–625.Basu, S. (1983) The Relationship Between Earnings Yield, Market Value, and Re-turns For NYSE Common Stocks: Further Evidence, Journal of Financial Eco-nomics 12: 129–156.Banz, R. (1981) The relationship between return and market value of commonstock, Journal of Financial Economics 9: 3–18.Black, F. (1972) Capital Market Equilibrium with Restricted Borrowing, Journal ofBusiness 45: 444–455.Brown, Kleidon, Ph., A., and Marsh, T. (1983) New Evidence on the Nature ofSize-Related Anomalies in Stock Prices, Journal of Financial Economics 12: 33–56.Bruce, C. (1997) The Einstein Paradox and other Mysteries Solved by SherlockHolmes. Basic Books.Chan, K.C. and Chen, N. F. (1991) Structural and Return Characteristics of Smalland Large Firms, Journal of Finance 46: 1467–1484.DeBondt, W.F.M., and Thaler, R. H. (1985) Does the Stock Market Overreact?,Journal of Finance, 40: 793–805.DeBondt, W.F.M., and Thaler, R. H. (1987) Further Evidence on Investor Over-reaction and Stock Market Seasonality, Journal of Finance 42: 557–580.Dreman, D. (1979) Contrarian Investment Strategy. Random House.Dreman, D. 1998) Contrarian Investment Strategies: The Next Generation. Simonand Schuster.Dreman, D., and Berry M. (1995) Overreaction, Underreaction and the Low P/EEffect, Financial Analysts Journal 51: 21–30.Fama, E. F. (1965) The Behavior of Stock Market Prices, Journal of Business 38: 34–105.Fama, E. F. (1970) Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and EmpiricalWork, Journal of Finance 25: 34–105.Fama, E. F. (1998) Market Efficiency, Long-Term Returns, and Behavioral Finance,Journal of Financial Economics 49: 283–306.。