Rogers and RIC PORON(r) Comparisons_Chinese

合集下载

经济理论中的福利国家

经济理论中的福利国家

经济理论中的福利国家Ξ郑秉文本文试图用经济学的基本原理来解释建立社会保障的理论依据,并以此来诠释西方福利国家存在的理性缘由,以期在主流经济学和社会保障及福利国家之间建立一个对话渠道。

在这个基础之上,试图运用经济学的理论框架来论证社会保障的建立和福利国家的存在不仅仅是由于“社会正义”的需要,更重要的,它还是由于“经济效率”的原因。

本文首先对战后西方世界正式宣布确立福利国家以来半个世纪中西方经济学研究社会保障和福利国家的学说史做一个概要性的回顾,对每个阶段的研究特点和热点问题予以分析讨论;然后着重对20世纪80年代至今西方经济学研究福利国家的成果和现状设立单独专题进行评析,即分别从宏观经济学、信息经济学、公共物品和公共选择理论等几个方面就社会保障和福利国家的效率功能进行私人保险市场与社会保障制度之间的效率比较,以期对失业、医疗健康、教育和养老等领域的社会保障和社会福利的存在根据给出结论。

关键词 经济学 社会保障 福利国家作者郑秉文,1955年生,中国社会科学院欧洲研究所教授(北京 100732)。

一、经济学研究福利国家的历史回顾虽然福利国家发端于英国、普及于欧洲,并几乎扩散于整个西方世界,但是,随着战后“大英帝国”的衰落和法、德等欧洲大陆国家的百废待兴,世界的经济中心早已转移到美国,于是,在1936年凯恩斯发表《就业、利息和货币通论》以后,作为一门解释社会经济现象的科学的经济学,其研究的中心也随之从英国移至美国。

于是,美国开始逐渐成为研究福利国家理论最活跃的发源地,成为以获得诺贝尔经济学奖为标志的世界级经济学大师辈出的摇篮,成为对社会保障和福利国家理论研究贡献最显著的地方。

战后以来,经济学或经济学家对福利国家研究的历史大致可以分为三个时期,即第一个阶段是20世纪60年代中期之前,第二个阶段是60年代中期至80年代初期,80年代初至今为第三个阶段。

20世纪60年代中期之前可以称为第一个阶段。

在这个时期,除英、法等一些老牌资本主义国家以外,社会保障在其它国家刚刚起步不久,福利制度发展态势逼人,运行状况良好,没有出现任何经济问题和财政障碍。

泡棉材料知识

泡棉材料知识
• 硅泡棉的化学组成:硅弹性体
• 硅弹性体是一种高交联的硅氧烷(醇)聚合物,化学名 称叫做Dimethicone Crosspolymer(聚二甲基硅氧 烷交联聚合物),属于硅橡胶的一种,即 Silicone Elastomers(硅胶弹性体),简称弹性体。
• 打个不恰当的比喻,就是一碗面条,如果煮的太久,面 条之间就会粘在一起(交联了),就会形成凝胶弹性体, 如果继续煮,水发少了烧糊了就变成固体的面块了(树 脂)
70年代末80年代初,聚氨酯合成材料的品种已经向系列化发展。并且开 发出反映注射成型的聚氨酯(RIM)
PORON的基本特性
• 弹性体 • 热固性 • 中等至高密度
– 190 – 480 kg/m3
• 片状涂覆
– 0.25 mm – 12.7 mm – 较薄材料需要PET基材
Silicones 硅泡棉
PORON 聚胺酯
聚氨酯发展简介
1937年德国化学家Otto Bayer发现了异氰酸酯与活泼氢化合物的聚合反 应,从而建立了聚氨酯化学的基础。
40年代德国人制取了聚氨酯粘合剂,50年代德国人亚当合成出聚氨酯混 炼胶(MPUR)和聚氨酯浇注橡胶(CPUR),商品名Vulkallan。
60年代以来聚氨酯聚氨酯浇注橡胶、热塑胶、泡沫塑料、涂料、粘合剂 等相继形成了工业化生产。
性质:应力松弛
10 psi
5 psi
时间
初始条件: 22ºC 及 50% 相對濕度
在夹具中压缩 聚合物
测量到达 50% 初始负荷的时间
重复于:
重复于: 70ºC
40ºC、55ºC、70ºC、85ºC、100ºC、125ºC、150ºC 100% 相對濕度 及 40ºC、55ºC、

The Pros and Cons of Globalization

The Pros and Cons of Globalization

The Pros and Cons of Globalization Globalization has been a hotly debated topic for decades, with proponents and opponents passionately arguing their respective positions. The concept of globalization refers to the interconnectedness and interdependence of countriesand their economies, facilitated by the rapid advancements in technology, communication, and transportation. While globalization has undeniably broughtabout numerous benefits, it has also sparked intense criticism and raised concerns about its potential drawbacks. In this essay, we will explore the pros and cons of globalization from various perspectives. One of the most significant advantagesof globalization is the unprecedented economic growth and development it has facilitated. By opening up markets and encouraging free trade, globalization has allowed countries to specialize in the production of goods and services in which they have a comparative advantage. This has led to increased efficiency, lower prices for consumers, and higher profits for businesses. Moreover, globalization has enabled the flow of foreign direct investment (FDI) and the transfer of technology, which has contributed to the economic development of many developing countries. In addition to economic benefits, globalization has also played a pivotal role in promoting cultural exchange and understanding. The interconnectedness of the world has allowed for the dissemination of ideas, values, and traditions across borders. This has led to a more diverse and interconnected global society, where individuals have the opportunity to learn from andappreciate different cultures. Furthermore, globalization has facilitated the spread of information and knowledge, leading to advancements in education, science, and technology on a global scale. On the other hand, globalization has been met with staunch criticism and opposition, particularly in relation to its impact on labor and employment. Critics argue that globalization has led to the outsourcing of jobs to countries with lower labor costs, resulting in job displacement and wage stagnation in developed countries. Moreover, the race to the bottom phenomenon, where multinational corporations seek the lowest production costs, has led to exploitation of workers in developing countries and the violation of labor rights. Another contentious issue surrounding globalization is its environmental impact. The increased interconnectedness of economies has led to a surge in globalproduction and consumption, resulting in heightened environmental degradation and the depletion of natural resources. The reliance on fossil fuels fortransportation and the production of goods has contributed to climate change and pollution, posing significant threats to the planet and future generations. Furthermore, globalization has been criticized for exacerbating income inequality within and between countries. While some regions and social groups have reaped the benefits of globalization, others have been left behind, facing economic marginalization and social exclusion. This has given rise to social unrest and political instability in various parts of the world, as marginalized communities feel disenfranchised and neglected by the forces of globalization. In conclusion, the debate surrounding the pros and cons of globalization is complex and multifaceted. While globalization has undoubtedly fostered economic growth, cultural exchange, and technological advancements, it has also raised significant concerns regarding labor rights, environmental sustainability, and income inequality. As the world continues to grapple with the implications of globalization, it is crucial to strike a balance between reaping its benefits and mitigating its adverse effects. Only through thoughtful and collaborative efforts can we harness the potential of globalization while addressing its challenges in a sustainable and equitable manner.。

PORON与泡棉的特性解读

PORON与泡棉的特性解读

PORON 常用型號一覽表
.20/.24/.32/.40/.48/.70 g/cm3 密度
• • • • • • • • • • • • (M) S Soft 柔軟 L Low modulus 中性 H Hard 硬 HH Hard-Hard 硬度雙倍 FH Far Hard 超硬度 X infinity 無限硬度 SR-S Slow Recovery and Soft 柔軟慢速回彈型 LE Low modulus with Elongation 柔軟彈力型 LT Low modulus and Thin 柔軟輕薄型 U/MO UL 認證(現由LO/FR--M系列替代) C/HF C 型號與現有 High Friction 高摩擦系數型 P PET (Mylar) 含塑膠薄膜
Special Coating made on the material surface
1) 高 抓 地 性
2) 零 污 染
® PORON
Coating Technology Development
<<流 離 物 質 測 試>>
1kg/cm2 Loaded
PORON Adherend
接觸表面
・ ・ ・ ・ ABS (塑膠) Acrylic (壓克力) Formica (麗光板-合成樹酯) Steel (鋼鐵)
UL-94 HBF 標準
現已經成為 OA (辦公室自動化設備) 與 PC/NB (電腦) 工業必備條件
輕, 薄, 短, 小
先進 精密儀器, 通訊器材, 設計趨勢
跟進 21 世紀市場需求 !!!
什麼是 PORON SR ?
SR PORON = Slow Rebound
慢速回彈

模切材料基础培训(新)(1)

模切材料基础培训(新)(1)


应用图解
应用领域
原材料特性及使用范围
2 .胶粘系列
包括3M,NITTO ,SONY,TESA,DIC,寺冈,罗曼,四维,力王等品牌的 双面胶及各式单面胶等 单/双面胶带的结构:
胶带结构分类
无基材双面胶
亚克力胶膜—亚克力胶水成膜,厚度0.05~0.15mm
棉纸双面胶—以棉纸或无纺布为基材,两面涂布胶水而 成,厚度0.10~0.20mm

@ @ Õ Å è @ Ò ¥ À Û S Ú H
@ @À Û S Ú
@ @ No.501K
@ No.501M
@ ] ü º ê @ Â â è H
@ @ z v S Ú @@ Y õ ¼ H
CR 泡棉 (氯丁橡胶) 橡胶泡棉 NR 泡棉 (丁腈橡胶) SBR 泡棉 (丁苯橡胶) EPDM 泡棉 (三元乙丙橡胶)
按发泡结构分类
质地柔软,吸水率高,压缩率高,适用 于吸音密封应用,如耳机的压缩海棉, 空调密封条等
开孔泡棉
闭孔泡棉
独立发泡,压缩残留率低,吸水率低, 隔热和缓冲性能良好,防尘好,适用于 电子产品密封防尘,防水减震等
PE 、PP离形膜等 )
原材料特性及使用范围
1. 背光模组系列 包含黑白双面胶,增光膜,扩散膜,反射膜,双面胶等,品牌有 YUPO,TORAY,KIMOTO, TEIJIN(帝人),SKC,KEIWA(惠和),3M等等.
黑白双面胶: 用于遮光,固定作用,除了黑白胶,还有黑黑胶,黑银胶等 增光膜: 使用在光源背后,增加光感,提升整体亮度 扩散片: 扩散膜的作用是将线光源(CCFL)和点光源(LED)通过光的折射、反射和散射转化 为一均匀的面光源,对于背光源组的结构,可将2、3张扩散膜重叠使用,从而达到更高的 正面亮度效果 反射膜: 反射膜的作用是将导光板背面或光源背面透射出来的光反射回组件中,将光源发 出来的光的损耗限制在最小程度,从而提高光的利用率,增加正面亮度。

Empirical processes of dependent random variables

Empirical processes of dependent random variables

2
Preliminaries
n i=1
from R to R. The centered G -indexed empirical process is given by (P n − P )g = 1 n
n
the marginal and empirical distribution functions. Let G be a class of measurabrocesses that have been discussed include linear processes and Gaussian processes; see Dehling and Taqqu (1989) and Cs¨ org˝ o and Mielniczuk (1996) for long and short-range dependent subordinated Gaussian processes and Ho and Hsing (1996) and Wu (2003a) for long-range dependent linear processes. A collection of recent results is presented in Dehling, Mikosch and Sorensen (2002). In that collection Dedecker and Louhichi (2002) made an important generalization of Ossiander’s (1987) result. Here we investigate the empirical central limit problem for dependent random variables from another angle that avoids strong mixing conditions. In particular, we apply a martingale method and establish a weak convergence theory for stationary, causal processes. Our results are comparable with the theory for independent random variables in that the imposed moment conditions are optimal or almost optimal. We show that, if the process is short-range dependent in a certain sense, then the limiting behavior is similar to that of iid random variables in that the limiting distribution is a Gaussian process and the norming √ sequence is n. For long-range dependent linear processes, one needs to apply asymptotic √ expansions to obtain n-norming limit theorems (Section 6.2.2). The paper is structured as follows. In Section 2 we introduce some mathematical preliminaries necessary for the weak convergence theory and illustrate the essence of our approach. Two types of empirical central limit theorems are established. Empirical processes indexed by indicators of left half lines, absolutely continuous functions, and piecewise differentiable functions are discussed in Sections 3, 4 and 5 respectively. Applications to linear processes and iterated random functions are made in Section 6. Section 7 presents some integral and maximal inequalities that may be of independent interest. Some proofs are given in Sections 8 and 9.

罗杰斯整机框贴泡棉选型资料(LCD Gasket Selection Guide-E

罗杰斯整机框贴泡棉选型资料(LCD Gasket Selection Guide-E

PORON ® is registered by Rogers and RICCompression force(N/mm²), Deflection↘Original thicknessFinal thickness -No adhesive (mm)PORON ®Grade(mm)0.140.150.180.200.250.300.400.500.600.700.800.90 1.0015-06021 P 0.530.069,74%0.048,72%0.021,66%0.014,62%15-06030 P 0.750.059,73%0.024,67%92-09020 P 0.500.069,64%0.042,60%0.017,50%0.010,40%92-09030 P 0.750.063,67%0.032,60%92-09039 P 1.000.070,70%0.027,60%92-12020 P 0.500.070,60%0.029,50%0.017,40%92-12030 P 0.750.054,60%0.022,47%92-12039 P 1.000.040,60%0.021,50%92-12049 P 1.250.060,68%0.028,60%0.016,52%92-12059 P 1.500.051,67%0.032,60%0.022,53%0.018,47%92-15039 P 1.000.042,60%0.019,50%0.012,40%92-15120 P 3.050.075,74%0.051,71%0.037,67%92-25021 P 0.530.152,43%92-25031 P 0.790.157,49%0.091,36%92-25041 P 1.040.082,33%ShockSeal™ Foams-Extreme impact protection79-09021 P 0.530.060,62%0.028,53%0.017,43%79-09030 P 0.750.081,67%0.043,60%0.020,47%79-09039 P 1.000.082,70%0.034,60%0.020,50%79-12021 P 0.530.137,62%0.055,53%0.031,43%0.017,25%79-12030 P 0.750.087,60%0.038,47%0.025,33%79-12039 P1.000.076,60%0.043,50%0.031,40%0.025,30%ThinStik™ Self-adhesive MaterialsCompression force (N/mm²), Deflection↘Original thicknessPORON® Series↓(mm)0.100.120.150.180.200.250.3015TS1-060210.530.160,81%0.082,77%0.037,72%0.020,66%15TS1-060300.750.169,80.3%0.069,76%0.045,73.7%0.019,66.7%0.010,60.5%92TS1-090200.500.360,80%0.167,76%0.066,71%0.031,65%0.021,60%92TS1-120200.500.068,64%0.046,60%0.021,50%79TS1-090210.530.211,77%0.092,72%0.051,66%0.035,62%* The final thickness should include the tolerance Nomenclature:15 TS1 06 021 04 P ThinStikThickness 012-500mils PETDensity 6-30pcf Color 04-Black ,90-GrayFomulation 15-Soft Seal,92-Extra Soft (Slow Rebound )Instruction :0.069,74%Compression force is 0.069N/mm²,deflection is 74%4.From the column under the final thickness 0.25mm, 15-06030P,92-09020P,92-09030P and 92-12020P are available.3.T1-T2=0.25mm It is the real filling thickness for foam.Higher forceMiddle forceLower forcePORON ®Urethane Foam - LCD Gasket selection guide(Compression Force< 10psi or 0.069N/mm²)2.Make sure the adhesive thickness ,ex. T2=0.05mm.Final thickness -with adhesive (mm)The information contained in this data sheet is intended to assist you in designing with Rogers’ High Performance Foam Materi als. It is not intended to and does not create anywarranties, express or implied, including any warranty of merchantability or fitness for a particular purpose or that the results shown on the data sheet will be achieved by a user for a particular purpose. The user should determine the suitability of Rogers’ High Performance Foam Materials for each applicati on.The Rogers logo, The world runs better with Rogers., PORON, ThinStik, and ShockSeal are licensed trademarks of Rogers Corporation. © 2010 Rogers Corporation, All rights reserved. Printed in U.S.A.,。

formative assessment and the design of instructional systems

formative assessment and the design of instructional systems

120 linkages are then identified. These in turn are shown to have implications for the design of instructional systems which are intended to develop the ability of students to exercise executive control over their own productive activities, and eventually to become independent and fully self-monitoring.
Introduction
This article is about the nature and function of formative assessment in the development of expertise. It is relevant to a wide variety of instructional systems in which student outcomes are appraised qualitatively using multiple criteria. The focus is on judgments about the quality of studentts, how they are made, how they may be refined, and how they may be put to use in bringing about improvement. The article is prompted by two overlapping concerns. The first is with the lack of a general theory of feedback and formative assessment in complex learning settings. The second concern follows from the common but puzzling observation that even when teachers provide students with valid and reliable judgments about the quality of their work, improvement does not necessarily follow. Students often show little or no growth or development despite regular, accurate feedback. The concern itself is with whether some learners fail to acquire expertise because of specific deficiencies in the instructional system associated with formative assessment. The discussion begins with definitions of feedback, formative assessment and qualitative judgments. This is followed by an analysis of certain patterns in teacher-student assessment interactions. A number of causal and conditional

journal of personality and social psychology

journal of personality and social psychology

Men and Women Are From Earth: Examining the Latent Structure of GenderBobbi J.Carothers Washington University in St.LouisHarry T.Reis University of RochesterTaxometric methods enable determination of whether the latent structure of a construct is dimensional or taxonic(nonarbitrary categories).Although sex as a biological category is taxonic,psychological gender differences have not been examined in this way.The taxometric methods of mean above minus below a cut,maximum eigenvalue,and latent mode were used to investigate whether gender is taxonic or dimensional.Behavioral measures of stereotyped hobbies and physiological characteristics(physical strength,anthropometric measurements)were examined for validation purposes,and were taxonic by sex. Psychological indicators included sexuality and mating(sexual attitudes and behaviors,mate selectivity, sociosexual orientation),interpersonal orientation(empathy,relational-interdependent self-construal), gender-related dispositions(masculinity,femininity,care orientation,unmitigated communion,fear of success,science inclination,Big Five personality),and intimacy(intimacy prototypes and stages,social provisions,intimacy with best friend).Constructs were with few exceptions dimensional,speaking to Spence’s(1993)gender identity theory.Average differences between men and women are not under dispute,but the dimensionality of gender indicates that these differences are inappropriate for diagnosing gender-typical psychological variables on the basis of sex.Keywords:gender,taxometric,latent structure,personality,sex differencesSupplemental materials:/10.1037/a0030437.suppIf you ain’t wrong,you’re right;If it ain’t day,it’s night...If it ain’t dry,it’s wet...Gotta be this or that.—Sunny Skylar Sex is the most pervasive method of categorizing people.We are more likely to categorize people based on gender than race(Stan-gor,Lynch,Duan,&Glass,1992).People use gender to sort individuals into categorical“natural kinds”more than they use20 other kinds of social categories(Haslam,Rothschild,&Ernst, 2000).Parents of newborns are usually first asked the sex of their child,even before questions about the child’s and mother’s health (Intons-Peterson&Reddel,1984).Because nearly all animal spe-cies come in only two forms,male and female,sex is an easy target for categorization.According to gender identity theory(Spence, 1984,1993),from infancy onward,whether a person is male or female pervades almost all human activities and experiences.Chil-dren use information about sex to aid in normal cognitive and social functioning(Kohlberg,1966;Martin&Halverson,1981). Infants as young as3months process images of male and female faces differently(Ramsey-Rennels&Langlois,2006).People au-tomatically identify an unfamiliar person’s sex without conscious effort(Brewer,1988),using the distinctiveness of male and female body shapes and gaits,and can determine a person’s sex seeing only how they walk in as little as2.7s(Barclay,Cutting,& Kozlowski,1978;Johnson&Tassinary,2005).Given the obvious evolutionary significance of a person’s sex,it may not be surprising that sex is used pervasively for socialBobbi J.Carothers,Center for Public Health Systems Science,Wash-ington University in St.Louis;Harry T.Reis,Department of Clinical and Social Sciences in Psychology,University of Rochester.This article is based on the doctoral dissertation of the first author while at University of Rochester.Portions of this research were pre-sented at meetings of the Society for Personality and Social Psychology and the International Association for Relationships Research.Data for this research were generously donated by Arthur Aron,Jennifer Aubé, Mark Barnett,David Buss,Mark Davis,William Graziano,Stephen Quackenbush,Harry Reis,Todd Shackelford,Brad Sheese,and Jeffry Simpson.We thank Chantal Levesque-Bristol and Bradley Bodenhamer for their valuable time in collecting the Midwestern Sample data set and John Ruscio for consultation on taxometric methods.Science inclina-tion data were made available by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.Anthropometric and National Health and Social Life Survey(NHSLS)data were made available by the Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research.Data for the National Health and Nutrition Examination Survey III were originally collected and prepared by the Centers for Disease Control and Preven-tion.Data for the NHSLS were originally collected by the University of Chicago and the National Opinion Research Center.Neither the collec-tors of the original data nor the consortium bears any responsibility for the analyses or interpretations presented here.Correspondence concerning this article should be addressed to Bobbi J. Carothers,Center for Public Health Systems Science,George Warren Brown School of Social Work,Washington University in St.Louis,Cam-pus Box1009,St.Louis,MO63112.E-mail:bcarothers@Journal of Personality and Social Psychology©2012American Psychological Association0022-3514/12/$12.00DOI:10.1037/a00304371categorization.In this light,Hyde(2005)posed a key question: Are men and women generally the same or essentially different?In lay conceptions,men and women tend to be seen as categorically different.When asked if men and women were“basically differ-ent”in1989,58%of a sample agreed(40%said they were similar, and2%had no opinion;Gallup,1991).Moreover,lay beliefs about the characteristics of one sex tend to be negatively correlated with beliefs about the characteristics of the other sex(e.g.,Foushee, Helmreich,&Spence,1979;Kahn&Yoder,1989).Because we categorize objects in order to simplify complex information,it has been suggested that people categorize men and women on the basis of sex to simplify a complex social world(Fiske,2010;Taylor, Fiske,Etcoff,&Ruderman,1978).In other words,if men and women differ,grouping people into sex categories makes sense as a simple and fast judgment rather than dealing with each individual as a unique case.That men and women do in fact differ in many important behaviors,at least some of which have meaningful effect sizes,reinforces this tendency(Eagly,1995;Hyde,2005).From these and other findings,it has been argued that sex may be the strongest example of essentialism in lay social cognition: the belief that categories possess distinctive“deep,hidden,and unchanging properties that make their members what they are”(Prentice&Miller,2007,p.202;see also Haslam et al.,2000). Furthermore,lay essentialist beliefs about sex differences are often grounded in genetic explanations(e.g.,Cole,Jayaratne,Cecchi, Feldbaum,&Petty,2007),endowing them with a sense of natu-ralness,presumed importance,and acceptability(Haslam et al., 2000;Prentice&Miller,2007;Wood&Eagly,2012).It may be no surprise,then,that popular models putting men and women into fundamentally distinct categories,such as the argument that men and women come from different planets(Gray,1992),often strike a resonant chord with lay audiences.Interestingly,despite many thousands of studies on sex differ-ences—in2011alone,PsycINFO reported3,370articles under the keyword human sex differences—psychological science has not explicitly demonstrated whether human sex differences in psycho-logical characteristics reflect categorical differences between men and women or whether they are a matter of degree.In all likeli-hood,this is because research has not directly considered the question.The present research adopted an empirical perspective for determining whether gender differences are best characterized as qualitative or as a matter of degree.As we explain,the preva-lence and magnitude of gender differences as they have been studied so far are uninformative with regard to this distinction, because differences per se do not tell us whether a taxon exists—that is,a categorical variable in which members form nonarbitrary (meaningful and naturally occurring)distinctive classes(Meehl, 1992;Meehl&Golden,1982;Ruscio&Ruscio,2008;Waller& Meehl,1998).We used taxometric methods to determine whether gender differences are taxonic(i.e.,representing the existence of distinct categories)or dimensional(i.e.,reflecting differences of degree).Existing Perspectives on the Taxon–DimensionDistinctionThe prevailing view among scholars working in this area is that most gender differences are dimensional.Arguably the clearest examples of this belief derive from the results of meta-analyses,which are often conducted to establish the extent to which men and women differ on a given variable(e.g.,Hyde,Fennema,&Lamon, 1990;Hyde&Linn,1988;Oliver&Hyde,1993).For example, Hyde(2005,2007)reviewed46meta-analyses of sex differences spanning diverse cognitive,social,and personality domains.The observed magnitude and pattern of these results led Hyde to conclude that men and women are substantially more similar than they are different,a conclusion that implies(but does not demon-strate)dimensionality.Another dimensionalist position is that gen-der differences reflect underlying continuous attributes,such as personality(e.g.,communion and agency;Spence&Helmreich, 1978),temperament(Brody,2000),and hormonal differences (Thornhill&Gangestad,2008).Researchers who emphasize the impact of culturally derived experiences similarly seem to adopt a dimensionalist orientation,by describing how specific experiences can shape the degree to which an individual develops specific traits or competencies(e.g.,Eagly,1987;Halpern,2012;Wood&Ea-gly,2002,2012).The dimensionalist position is also popular in social neuroscience,in which arguments about the plasticity and “deep intricacy”(Eliot,2011,p.897)of the human brain are cited to explain why reliable sex differences in brain structure and function may have relatively little behavioral impact(e.g.,Eliot, 2009,2011;Halpern,2012).Nevertheless,perhaps because the taxon–dimension distinction has not received explicit empirical attention,some researchers appear to favor a more categorical interpretation of gender differ-ences.For example,many evolutionarily oriented researchers view men’s and women’s social behavior as categorically distinct,re-flecting the different adaptive tasks implied by biological differ-ences between men and women(e.g.,Geary,2010).These distinc-tions are reflected in sexually dimorphic brain structures,such as men’s larger and more lateralized brains(see Ellis et al.,2008,for recent meta-analyses)or neural regions that show differential elaboration in response to activation by sex hormones(see Geary, 2010,for a review).Likewise,researchers who theorize about sexuality and mating-related behaviors from an evolutionary per-spective typically favor categorical accounts in their conceptual-ization of gender differences(e.g.,Buss,1995;Buss&Schmitt, 1993;Schmitt,2002).More generally,Zahn-Waxler and Polanichka(2004)reviewed several theoretical models positing qualitative differences in the expression and etiology of antisocial behavior in boys and girls. Another example is the“tend-and-befriend model,”which pro-poses that men’s and women’s responses to stress are fundamen-tally different(Taylor et al.,2000),linking these behaviors to the influence of oxytocin.Indeed,the fact that researchers sometimes analyze data from men and women separately(Kashy&Kenny, 2000),and the insistence by some editors and reviewers that researchers routinely analyze their data for gender differences(see Baumeister,1988;Eagly,1987;and McHugh,Koeske,&Frieze, 1986,for varied positions in this debate),implies belief in at least the possibility that men’s and women’s behavior may be categor-ically distinct.If,as mentioned above,most scholars are skeptical about the general idea that in terms of social behavior men and women represent natural kinds,why does categorical thinking persist?One reason,we propose,is that no existing research has examined explicitly the distinction between categorical and dimensional models.As described in the next section,documentation of gender2CAROTHERS AND REISdifferences in and of themselves is insufficient to conclusively establish that gender differences are dimensional,or whether they might be taxonic.The research described in this article was de-signed to provide such evidence.Understanding Dimensions and TaxaOne reason why the underlying nature of gender differences has been difficult to address is that although biological sex is clearly a categorical variable,the variables commonly of interest to re-searchers and laypersons alike tend to be dimensional(e.g.,mas-culinity,femininity,school achievement,depression,aggression), varying along a continuum.The statement that men are more aggressive than women,for example,implicitly assumes that there is one group of people who are high in aggression(men)and another group of people who are low in aggression(women).This assumption treats an observed mean difference between men and women as a special kind of category called a taxon.Examples of taxa include animal species(gophers vs.chipmunks),certain phys-ical illnesses(e.g.,one either has meningitis or not),and biological sex.To distinguish a taxon from a mere category,Waller and Meehl (1998)used the example of students receiving an A on an exam. Though A students are in a different category from B students, they are not a taxon because the dividing line between an A and a B is determined by the grader’s cutoff on a dimensional scale of performance.Knowing a person’s grade in one subject is relatively uninformative about other attributes.However,when individuals are members of a taxon,they are more likely possess traits that are characteristic of that taxon than nonmembers.For example,know-ing that Person A has two X chromosomes allows one to accu-rately conclude that Person A will develop breasts,ovulate,have little facial hair,and exhibit all other characteristics associated with being female.Like many taxa,sex has a genetic basis;with few exceptions,a person is either XX or XY.The indicators for sex(i.e.,genetic makeup,anatomy,physiology)are nearly infal-lible.As Meehl(1995)put it,“There are gophers,there are chipmunks,but there are no gophmunks”(p.268).When applied to sex,“between day and night there is dusk.But between male and female there is...essentially nothing”(Myers,2008,p.164).1 We sought to empirically determine whether standard gender differences are better conceived as taxonic or dimensional.Al-though men and women may differ on average in myriad ways, these differences may be dimensional,reflecting different amounts of a given attribute assessed along a single dimension,or qualita-tive,sorted into fundamentally distinct categories.Taxometric analysis is concerned not only with the magnitude of differences but also with the pattern and distribution of differences across multiple variables.As we will show,this difference has consider-able importance for understanding the fundamental nature of gen-der differences.What exactly is a taxon?In the simplest sense,a taxon means that a set of variables is essentially uncorrelated within groups due to a tendency toward restriction of range.However,because mean differences exist on each variable,correlations appear when the groups are combined in a single analysis.This is shown in Figure 1.For example,let the variables in Figure1be hair length and height;Group1is men and Group2is women.Within each group, there is no correlation.But when the two groups are combined in a single analysis,because the sex difference introduces additional variability for each variable,the correlation can be large(Ruscio, Haslam,&Ruscio,2006;Ruscio&Ruscio,2008).(This is a version of the well-known aggregation fallacy identified by Ep-stein,1986.)Thus,understanding the pattern of within-and between-group correlations across multiple variables measured simultaneously in a single sample(rather than group distributions on variables from isolated samples)is necessary to examine the latent structure of gender.This is the novel contribution of the present research.Why Distinguish Dimensions and Taxa?There are several reasons why it is important to determine the latent structure of gender(Ruscio&Ruscio,2008).First,whereas dimensional variations may arise from multiple additive influ-ences,categorical differences require mechanisms capable of cre-ating a dichotomous(on/off)structure.Second,knowledge about the underlying structure of a construct can inform classification, that is,whether individuals vary along dimensions or belong to distinct groups.Third,whereas categories imply that group com-parisons are most appropriate for statistical analysis,dimensional variables are more appropriately analyzed by continuous correla-tional methods.Taxometric methods have been used profitably in several areas of psychological research.For example,although the Diagnostic and Statistical Manual of Mental Disorders“is a categorical classification that divides mental disorders into types based on criteria sets with defining features”(American Psychiatric Asso-ciation,2000,p.xxxi),Widiger and Trull(2007)concluded that existing data better support a dimensional model of personality disorder.Other constructs sometimes thought to be categorical but found to be dimensional include attachment(Fraley&Spieker, 2003;Fraley&Waller,1998;Roisman,Fraley,&Belsky,2007) and depression(Ruscio&Ruscio,2000;Whisman&Pinto,1997). On the other hand,constructs found to be taxonic include schizo-phrenia(Meehl,1962,1990),schizotypy(Korfine&Lenzen-weger,1995;Lenzenweger&Korfine,1992),self-monitoring (Gangestad&Snyder,1985,1991),and Type A behavior(Strube, 1989).In each instance,researchers have used this information to refine and advance theoretical models.Haslam and Kim(2002) provide a more extensive review of taxometric research.Dimensions and Taxa as Applied to GenderAs noted earlier,gender research has made little or no use of taxometric methods so far.Clearly,many gender differences are present in personality and social behavior(for reviews,see Dindia &Canary,2006;Ellis et al.,2008;Gilligan,1982;Halpern,2012; Maccoby&Jacklin,1974).Hyde’s2005(see also Hyde,2007) review of46meta-analyses of gender differences revealed numer-ous consistent and reliable differences between men and women. Some of the personality and social variables producing larger differences included interruptions,smiling,self-disclosure,aggres-sion,sexuality,anxiety,assertiveness,agreeableness,body-1Though the existence of intersex individuals may call this into ques-tion,the rarity of their occurrence casts them as the exceptions that prove the rule.3MEN AND WOMEN ARE FROM EARTHesteem,and self-efficacy about computer use.Hyde’s review did not include many other variables of interest to personality and social psychologists,such as sex differences in mating and rela-tional strategies (Buss &Barnes,1986;Buss,Larsen,Westen,&Semmelroth,1992;Buss &Schmitt,1993;Buss &Shackelford,1997;Kenrick,Sadalla,Groth,&Trost,1990)or in responses to stress (Taylor et al.,2000).(Other specific study variables are described later in this article.)What is important to note here is that each of these gender differences reflects a reliable difference between men and women.However,the existence of a gender difference in and of itself,and regardless of its magnitude,does not provide direct empirical support for its dimensionality or taxonic-ity.Rather,as explained above,multiple indicators,along with their intercorrelations,must be examined together in the same sample.We sought to establish that gender differences are better repre-sented as dimensional than as taxonic constructs in a more defin-itive way than prior research has done.The implications of this distinction are important.Should gender be taxonic,contrary to prevailing beliefs,men and women could legitimately be said to be qualitatively different in relevant domains.Knowing only that a person was male,we could also infer that he would be relatively aggressive,good in math,poor in verbal skills,primarily interested in short-term mating,less agreeable,and so on,to the same general degree of accuracy as inferring biological characteristics relevant to sex—for example,large waist-to-hip ratio and deeper voice.This is because if gender were taxonic,the relevant behaviors would co-occur in all members of the class.In other words,most men would score similarly to each other on all these indicators,as would women,with little overlap between the two groups.On the other hand,if gender is dimensional,as scholars commonly as-sume,a person’s gender-appropriate behavior on one variable would not imply being high on other gender-related variables.Should our results support dimensionality,scholars would have a stronger empirical basis for their belief.The Present ResearchAs discussed above,the underlying structure of gender differ-ences is implicit in many theoretical accounts of social behavior.Our research was designed to provide explicit evidence about a wide variety of psychological traits in which men and women differ.These analyses evaluated the likelihood that existing gender differences are better represented as dimensional or taxonic.This work differs from more exploratory taxometric research because the sex of participants in the samples is already known.If a taxon appears,we can determine whether it is based on sex (in line with what Meehl,1992,referred to as a real data pseudoproblem).In other words,participants’actual sex is the “gold standard”of prediction.Because the Bayesian distributions obtained from taxo-metric analyses graphically represent the probability that each individual is a member of the taxon group,one can determine whether whatever taxa emerge from these analyses accurately sort men into one group and women into the other.2Our analyses were conducted on a series of domains commonly studied by researchers interested in differences between women and men.These are detailed below.MethodData Set RecruitmentWe selected data sets on the basis of three major criteria:that they included variables that have been important in the sex-2One somewhat related approach in prior research is Lippa’s work on gender diagnosticity (e.g.,Lippa,1991;Lippa &Connelly,1990).That research used Bayesian methods to try to find traits that would accurately categorize men and women.Although the idea of gender diagnosticity implies that gender is taxonic with respect to certain indicators,it does not establish whether gender is taxonic ordimensional.Figure 1.Within-group versus full-sample correlation patterns underlying taxometric analysis.Within-group correlations tend to be small,but can be high over the full sample.Adapted from Multivariate Taxometric Procedures:Distinguishing Types From Continua (p.13,Figure 3.1),by N.G.Waller and P.E.Meehl,1998,Thousand Oaks,CA:Sage.Copyright 1998by Sage Publications.4CAROTHERS AND REISdifferences-in-social-behavior literature,that they came as close as possible to meeting statistical criteria for taxometric analyses,and that they were available to us.We began by performing a literature search and contacted several researchers regarding data from articles that preliminarily appeared to meet the analysis requirements.In order to meet the requirements of taxometric analysis,data sets were considered eligible if there were at least300participants,the gender balance in the sample was no worse that60:40,and there were at least three contin-uous and theoretically linked measures showing significant gender differences.Researchers who had collected these data sets were asked to share them with us.Other researchers with known experience in gender difference research were contacted and asked whether they had any data fitting the above criteria that they would be willing to share.Altogether,31researchers were contacted:Nine provided data;15reported having no data sets that fit the requirements or that requested data were no longer available(some referred us to second authors);seven did not reply.Four data sets were available online.We also collected further data on several relational,interper-sonal,and behavioral variables in one additional sample to exam-ine the taxonicity of gender across these constructs,sometimes repeating earlier measurements with ambiguous results for repli-cation purposes.This sample of109men and167women3with a mean age of21.15years(SDϭ7.68)was drawn from an introductory-level psychology class at a large midwestern univer-sity and is periodically mentioned through the rest of the article as the Midwestern Sample.Where a data set provided multiple scales along with the raw items for each scale,several analyses could be performed.First, analyses were performed including all mean scores of scales showing a significant sex difference.Second,when individual items were made available,analyses on the individual scales themselves could be performed.Taxometric ProceduresThree common techniques for taxometric analyses are mean above minus below a cut(MAMBAC),maximum eigenvalue (MAXEIG),and latent mode(L-Mode;Waller&Meehl,1998). For MAXEIG and L-Mode,at least three variables measuring the desired construct are submitted for analysis(MAMBAC can work with as few as two variables),and the shape of the obtained function is used to judge whether the construct is taxonic or dimensional.Taxonic data produce peaked MAMBAC and MAXEIG curves,and bimodal L-Mode curves. Dimensional data yield flat or U-shaped MAMBAC curves,flat MAXEIG curves,and unimodal L-Mode curves.MAXEIG re-sults can also be used to assign a Bayesian probability that each individual belongs to the taxon group.Taxonic data produce U-shaped histograms with clumps at the tails of the x-axis.With taxonic constructs,some individuals have a very high proba-bility of being a member of the taxon group,and everyone else has a very low probability,with few people in the middle “undecided”ranges.Dimensional constructs produce less dis-cernible Bayesian distributions,meaning that many cases can-not be classified into one group or the other with certainty.In the event that a taxon is identified,it can be used to determine whether men and women were accurately sorted.Dimensional data can also produce U-shaped distributions(Ruscio et al., 2006),so a taxonic-looking Bayesian distribution must be in-terpreted within the context of the other methods.A dimensional-looking Bayesian distribution,however,makes a strong case for dimensionality.Interpreting distributions produced by these three methods can be subjective.In the ideal case the plots obtained fit either of the alternatives mentioned above,but in practice these graphs are sometimes ambiguous.We used three methods to control for this ambiguity.First,we drew conclusions only from results that replicated consistently with all three methods.Each proce-dure tests for taxonicity in a different way,and because inter-pretation is largely visual,most researchers recommend that multiple methods be used to confirm one another(Waller& Meehl,1998).Second,simulation methods(Ruscio et al.,2006) help determine the suitability of data for taxometric analyses. On the basis of properties of the actual data(n,number of indicators,correlations between indicators,skew),it is possible to simulate what the data would look like if they were taxonic or dimensional.Data are considered appropriate for taxometric analysis if the simulations are distinguishable.Taxonic and dimensional simulations that are too similar to be distinguished from each other indicate that the data are unsuitable for that method.Third,ambiguous results can be compared with their parison curve fit indices(CCFIs;Ruscio et al., 2006)provide an objective measure of whether the curve gen-erated by the actual data is closer to its taxonic(CCFI of1)or dimensional(CCFI of0)simulation.Judgments based on visual inspection should supersede CCFI results when they disagree (Ruscio et al.,2006).The CCFI for each analysis is reported in Table1.In Figures 2–4and A1–A22(see Appendix,included in the supplemental materials),MAMBAC results are the upper left quadrant, MAXEIG in the upper right,L-Mode in the lower left,and Bayes-ian probabilities in the lower right.For MAMBAC and MAXEIG, two graphs are presented,one superimposing the actual data over simulated taxonic data(left panel)and the other superimposing the identical data over simulated dimensional data(right panel). L-Mode is presented in one panel,with actual data drawn in the heavy solid line,simulated taxonic data drawn in the lighter solid line,and simulated dimensional data drawn in the dotted line. Comparison of the degree to which actual results match these simulations was used to assign a result to each analysis.Numerical output is also given in the form of base rate estimates(i.e.,the proportion of the sample assigned to the taxon)and is provided in the supplemental materials(see Supplemental Table1).These estimates are unreliable in dimensional data for all three methods, for if there are no true taxon or complement groups,the concept of “base rate”is moot,though consistent estimates may indicate taxonicity.3Seven men and five women were deleted for indicating nonheterosexu-ality to prevent the possibility of sexual orientation from introducing an additional taxon or contributing additional unaccounted-for variance.Re-sults including these individuals were similar to those reported here.We do admit to a heterosexual bias in our treatment of gender indicators,and although the extent to which sexual orientation can influence the results of gender taxonicity is intriguing,it is beyond the scope of this article.5MEN AND WOMEN ARE FROM EARTH。

罗杰斯公司(Rogers泡棉材料PORON 手机应用精品PPT课件

罗杰斯公司(Rogers泡棉材料PORON 手机应用精品PPT课件
0 .0 4 2 1 0 .0 5 9 1 0 .0 7 0 2 0 .1 4 0 1 0 .1 6 2 0 0 .2 5 7 7 0 .3 3 9 4 0 .3 8 9 7
0 .0 1 0 1 0 .0 1 2 6 0 .0 1 6 8 0 .0 3 2 1 0 .0 3 2 2 0 .0 5 3 8 0 .0 6 9 7 0 .1 2 0 4 0 .1 4 4 1 0 .1 5 1 6 0 .2 0 5 0 0 .2 2 3 1 0 .2 5 5 4 0 .4 3 5 0
应力松弛测试
PORON在不同温度下对多种材料
179 周 / 3.4年
压缩率
Stress (N/mm2)
CFD Comparison of Competitor Foams with PORON Soft Seal Urethanes
0.09 0.08 0.07 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01
厚度
012 - 500 mils 0.3mm – 12.7mm
颜色&是否带PET
04- Black 90- Soft Seal Gray
P- PET Support
产品列表
网址链接
扬声器垫圈 • 92 • 30
LCD衬垫 • 15 • 92 • 30
小屏幕衬垫 • 15 • 92 • 30
听筒垫圈 • 92 • 30
试验结果显示了泡棉材料抗压缩形变指标的重要性 以及与密封效果之间的关系 同为1.0mm厚的两种泡棉试样单面附胶固定在两 块玻璃板间,压缩比为30%。 整个装置与淀粉混合, 放入密封袋静置7天后翻滚5分钟完成第一个测试 周期,持续室验直至垫圈框内明显出现淀粉颗粒为 止。右图是聚丙烯(PP)泡棉在1个周期后的结果。左 图是聚氨酯PORON Soft Seal 15-06039在3个周 期后的试验结果。显而易见,PORON聚氨酯泡棉防 尘能力出众。

罗杰斯公司(Rogers泡棉材料PORON 手机应用精品PPT课件

罗杰斯公司(Rogers泡棉材料PORON 手机应用精品PPT课件
15-06030 P 15-06039 P 92-09030 P 92-12030 P 92-09039 P 92-15039 P 92-12039 P 92-12049 P 92-12059 P 92-25024 P 92-25031 P 92-25041 P 30-25037 P 30-25047 P
D eflectio n (% )
83
70 80 70 85
60 73 60 80 73 33 73 80
40 60 40 60 70 60 70 70 70 43 76 51 80 62
20 47 20 47 60 47 60 60 60 68 25 34 73 49 62
33 50 33 33 50 50 50 60 67 18 37 52 47 58
手机中的应用
闪光灯垫圈 FPC压合 连接器压合 侧键 元器件支撑 插孔密封 马达减震 遮光 内置天线衬垫
电池衬垫 • 92 • 30
填隙方案 (Gap Filling)
扣合力
• LCD垫圈扣合力在0.07N/mm2左右,其他应用需 视具体要求而定,一般应大于该值
压缩比
• 建议在30%-80%之间
间隙(Gap)公差
0 .7 5 1 .0 0 1 .0 0 1 .0 0 1 .0 0 1 .2 4 0 .7 9 1 .5 0 1 .0 4 0 .9 4 1 .1 9 1 .6 3
1 .0 0 1 .0 0 1 .0 0 1 .0 0 0 .9 4 1 .2 4 1 .5 0 1 .0 4 1 .1 9 1 .6 3
手机常用的级别: 15, 92, 30
产品描述
4701-92-12020-04P
市场代码
4701 General - Resilient 4790 General – Slow Rebound

firms constracts and trade structure

firms constracts and trade structure

Firms,Contracts,and Trade Structure∗Pol AntràsHarvard University and NBERThis Version:May2003AbstractRoughly one-third of world trade is intrafirm trade.This paper starts by unveiling two systematic patterns in the volume of intrafirm trade.In a panelof industries,the share of intrafirm imports in total U.S.imports is signifi-cantly higher,the higher the capital intensity of the exporting industry.Ina cross-section of countries,the share of intrafirm imports in total U.S.im-ports is significantly higher,the higher the capital-labor ratio of the exportingcountry.I then show that these patterns can be rationalized in a theoreti-cal framework that combines a Grossman-Hart-Moore view of thefirm witha Helpman-Krugman view of international trade.In particular,I develop anincomplete-contracting,property-rights model of the boundaries of thefirm,which I then incorporate into a standard trade model with imperfect compe-tition and product differentiation.The model pins down the boundaries ofmultinationalfirms as well as the international location of production,and itis shown to predict the patterns of intrafirm trade identified above.Econo-metric evidence reveals that the model is consistent with other qualitative andquantitative features of the data.Keywords Property-rights theory,Multinational Firms,International Trade, Intrafirm Trade.JEL Classification Numbers D23,F12,F14,F21,F23,L22,L33∗The shorter,final version was published in the Quarterly Journal of Economics in November 2003.I am grateful to Daron Acemoglu,George-Marios Angeletos,Gene Grossman,and Jaume Ven-tura for invaluable guidance,and to Manuel Amador,Lucia Breierova,Francesco Caselli,Fritz Foley, Gino Gancia,Andrew Hertzberg,Elhanan Helpman,Bengt Holmström,Ben Jones,Oscar Lander-retche,Alexis León,Gerard Padró-i-Miquel,Thomas Philippon,Diego Puga,Jeremy Stein,Joachim Voth,two anonymous referees,and the editor(Edward Glaeser)for very helpful comments.I have also benefited from suggestions by seminar participants at UC Berkeley,Chicago GSB,Columbia, Harvard,LSE MIT,NBER,Northwestern,NYU,Princeton,UC San Diego,Stanford,and Yale. Financial support from the Bank of Spain is gratefully acknowledged.All remaining errors are my own.Correspondence:pantras@.Correspondence:Department of Economics, Harvard University,Littauer230,Cambridge,MA02138.Email:pantras@.1IntroductionRoughly one-third of world trade is intrafirm trade.In1994,42.7percent of the total volume of U.S.imports of goods took place within the boundaries of multinational firms,with the share being36.3percent for U.S.exports of goods(Zeile,1997).In spite of the clear significance of these internationalflows of goods between affiliated units of multinationalfirms,the available empirical studies on intrafirm trade provide little guidance to international trade theorists.In this paper I unveil some novel patterns exhibited by the volume of U.S.intrafirm imports and I argue that these patterns can be rationalized combining a Grossman-Hart-Moore view of thefirm, together with a Helpman-Krugman view of international trade.In a hypothetical world in whichfirm boundaries had no bearing on the pattern of international trade,one would expect only random differences between the behavior of the volume of intrafirm trade and that of the total volume of trade.In particular,the share of intrafirm trade in total trade would not be expected to correlate significantly with any of the classical determinants of international trade.Figure1provides afirst illustration of how different the real world is from this hypothetical world.In a panel consisting of23manufacturing industries and four years of data(1987,1989,1992,and1994),the share of intrafirm imports in total U.S.imports is significantly higher,the higher the capital intensity in production of the exporting industry.Figure1indicates thatfirms in the U.S.tend to import capital-intensive goods,such as chemical products,within the boundaries of their firms,while they tend to import labor-intensive goods,such as textile products,from unaffiliated parties.1Figure2unveils a second strong pattern in the share of intrafirm imports.In a cross-section of28countries,the share of intrafirm imports in total U.S.imports is significantly higher,the higher the capital-labor ratio of the exporting country. U.S.imports from capital-abundant countries,such as Switzerland,tend to take place 1The pattern in Figure1is consistent with Gereffi’s(1999)distinction between‘producer-driven’and‘buyer-driven’international economic networks.Thefirst,he writes,is“characteristic of capi-tal-and technology-intensive industries[...]in which large,usually transnational,manufacturers play the central roles in coordinating production networks”(p.41).Conversely,‘buyer-driven’networks are common in“labor-intensive,consumer goods industries”and are characterized by “highly competitive,locally owned,and globally dispersed production systems”(pp.42-43).The emphasis is my own.Figure1:Share of Intrafirm U.S.Imports and Relative Factor IntensitiesNotes:The Y-axis corresponds to the logarithm of the share of intrafirm imports in total U.S. imports for 23 manufacturingindustries and 4 years: 1987, 1989, 1992, 1994. The X-axis measures the log of that industry’s ratio of capital stock to totalemployment in the corresponding year, using U.S. data. See Table A.1. for industry codes and Appendix A.4. for data sources. Figure2:Share of Intrafirm U.S.Imports and Relative Factor EndowmentsNotes:The Y-axis corresponds to the logarithm of the share of intrafirm imports in total U.S. imports for 28 exportingcountries in 1992. The X-axis measures the log of the exporting country’s physical capital stock divided by its total number ofworkers. See Table A.2. for country codes and Appendix A.4. for details on data sources.between affiliated units of multinationalfirms.Conversely,U.S.imports from capital-scarce countries,such as Egypt,occur mostly at arm’s length.This second fact suggests that the well-known predominance of North-North trade in total world trade is even more pronounced within the intrafirm component of trade.2 Why are capital-intensive goods transacted within the boundaries of multinational firms,while labor-intensive goods are traded at arm’s length?3To answer this ques-tion,I build on the theory of thefirm initially exposited in Coase(1937)and later de-veloped by Williamson(1985)and Grossman and Hart(1986),by which activities take place wherever transaction costs are minimized.In particular,I develop a property-rights model of the boundaries of thefirm in which,in equilibrium,transaction costs of using the market are increasing in the capital intensity of the imported good. To explain the cross-country pattern in Figure2,I embed this partial-equilibrium framework in a general-equilibrium,factor-proportions model of international trade, with imperfect competition and product differentiation,along the lines of Helpman and Krugman(1985).The model pins down the boundaries of multinationalfirms as well as the international location of production.Bilateral tradeflows between any two countries are uniquely determined and the implied relationship between in-trafirm trade and relative factor endowments is shown to correspond to that in Figure 2.The result naturally follows from the interaction of comparative advantage and transaction-cost minimization.In drawingfirm boundaries,I build on the seminal work of Grossman and Hart (1986).I consider a world of incomplete contracts in which ownership corresponds to the entitlement of some residual rights of control.When parties undertake non-contractible,relationship-specific investments,the allocation of residual rights has a critical effect on each party’s ex-post outside option,which in turn determines each party’s ex-ante incentives to invest.Ex-ante efficiency(i.e.,transaction-cost mini-2This is consistent with comparisons based on foreign direct investment(FDI)data.In the year 2000,more than85%of FDIflows occured between developed countries(UNCTAD,2001),while the share of North-North trade in total world trade was only roughly70%(World Trade Organization, 2001).3At this point,a natural question is whether capital intensity and capital abundance are truly the crucial factors driving the correlations in Figures1and2.In particular,these patterns could in principle be driven by other omitted factors.Section4will present formal econometric evidence in favor of the emphasis placed on capital intensity and capital abundance in this paper.mization)then dictates that residual rights should be controlled by the party whose investment contributes most to the value of the relationship.To explain the higher propensity to integrate in capital-intensive industries,I extend the framework of Grossman and Hart(1986)by allowing the transferability of certain investment decisions.In situations in which the default option for one of the parties(a supplier in the model)is too unfavorable,the allocation of residual rights may not suffice to induce adequate levels of investment.In such situations,I show that the hold-up problem faced by the party with the weaker bargaining position may be alleviated by having another party(afinal-good producer in the model)contribute to the former’s relationship-specific investments.Investment-sharing alleviates the hold-up problem faced by suppliers,but naturally increases the exposure offinal-good producers to opportunistic behavior,with the exposure being an increasing function of the contribution to investment costs.If cost sharing is large enough,ex-ante efficiency is shown to command that residual rights of control,and thus ownership,be assigned to thefinal-good producer,thus giving rise to vertical integration.Conversely,when the contribution of thefinal-good producer is relatively minor,the model predicts outsourcing.What determines then the extent of cost sharing?Business practices suggest that, in many situations,investments in physical capital are easier to share than invest-ments in labor input.Dunning(1993,p.455-456)describes several cost-sharing practices of multinationalfirms in their relations with independent subcontractors. Among others,these include provision of used machinery and specialized tools and equipment,prefinancing of machinery and tools,and procurement assistance in ob-taining capital equipment and raw materials.There is no reference to cost sharing in labor costs,other than in labor grom and Roberts(1993)discuss the particular example of General Motors,which pays forfirm-and product-specific capital equipment needed by their suppliers,even when this equipment is located in the suppliers’facilities.Similarly,in his review article on Japanesefirms,Aoki(1990, p.25)describes the close connections betweenfinal-good manufacturers and their suppliers but writes that“suppliers have considerable autonomy in other respects, for example in personnel administration”.Even withinfirm boundaries,cost sharing seems to mostly take place when capital investments are involved.In particular,Ta-ble1indicates that British affiliates of U.S.-based multinationals tend to have much more independence in their employment decisions(e.g.,in hiring of workers)than in theirfinancial decisions(e.g.,in their choice of capital investment projects).Table1.Decision-Making in U.S.based multinationals%of British affiliates in which parent influence on decision is strong or decisiveSetting offinancial targets51Union recognition4 Preparation of yearly budget20Collective bargaining1 Acquisition of funds for working capital44Wage increases8 Choice of capital investment projects33Numbers employed13 Financing of investment projects46Lay-offs/redundancies10 Target rate of return on investment68Hiring of workers10 Sale offixed assets30Recruitment of executives16 Dividend policy82Recruitment of senior managers13 In this paper,I do not intend to explain why cost sharing is more significant in physical capital investments than in labor input investments.This may be the result of suppliers having superior local knowledge in hiring workers,or it may be explained by the fact that managing workers requires a physical presence in the production plant.Regardless of the source of this asymmetry,the model developed in section2 shows that if cost sharing is indeed more significant in capital-intensive industries, the propensity to integrate will also be higher in these industries.In order to explain the trade patterns shown in Figures1and2,I then embed the partial-equilibrium relationship betweenfinal-good producers and suppliers into a general-equilibrium framework with a continuum of goods in each of two industries.In section3,I open this economy to international trade,allowingfinal-good producers to obtain inter-mediate inputs from foreign suppliers.In doing so,I embrace a Helpman-Krugman view of international trade with imperfect competition and product differentiation, by which countries specialize in producing certain varieties of intermediate inputs and export them worldwide.Trade in capital-intensive intermediate inputs will be trans-acted withinfirm boundaries.Trade in labor-intensive goods will instead take place at arm’s length.The model solves for bilateral tradeflows between any two countries,and predicts the share of intrafirm imports in total imports to be increasing in the capital-labor ratio of the exporting country.4This is the correlation implied by Fig-ure2.Moreover,some of the quantitative implications of the model are successfully tested in section4.This paper is related to several branches in the literature.On the one hand, it is related to previous theoretical studies that have rationalized the existence of multinationalfirms in general-equilibrium models of international trade.5Helpman’s (1984)model introduced a distinction betweenfirm-level and plant-level economies of scale that has proven crucial in later work.In his model,multinationals arise only outside the factor price equalization set,when afirm has an incentive to geograph-ically separate the capital-intensive production of an intangible asset(headquarter services)from the more labor-intensive production of goods.Following the work of Markusen(1984)and Brainard(1997),an alternative branch of the literature has developed models rationalizing the emergence of multinationalfirms in the absence of factor endowment differences.In these models,multinationals will exist in equilib-rium whenever transport costs are high and wheneverfirm-specific economies of scale are high relative to plant-specific economies of scale.6,7These two approaches to the multinationalfirm share a common failure to properly model the crucial issue of internalization.These models can explain why a domestic firm might have an incentive to undertake part of its production process abroad,but they fail to explain why this foreign production will occur withinfirm boundaries(i.e., within multinationals),rather than through arm’s length subcontracting or licensing.4This second part of the argument is based on the premise that capital-abundant countries tend to produce mostly capital-intensive commodities.Romalis(2002)has recently shown that the empirical evidence is indeed consistent with factor proportions being a key determinant of the structure of international trade.5The literature builds on the seminal work of Helpman(1984)and Markusen(1984).For extensive reviews see Caves(1996)and Markusen and Maskus(2001).6The intuition for this result is straightforward:whenfirm-specific economies of scale are im-portant,costs are minimized by undertaking all production within a singlefirm.If transport costs are high and plant-specific economies of scale are small,then it will be profitable to set up multiple production plants to service the different local markets.Multinationals are thus of the“horizontal type”.7Recently,the literature seems to have converged to a“unified”view of the multinationalfirm, merging the factor-proportions(or“vertical”)approach of Helpman(1984),together with the “proximity-concentration”trade-offimplicit in Brainard(1997)and others.Markusen and Maskus (2001)refer to this approach as the“Knowledge-Capital Model”and claim that its predictions are widely supported by the evidence.In the same way that a theory of thefirm based purely on technological considerations does not constitute a satisfactory theory of thefirm(c.f.,Tirole,1988,Hart,1995), a theory of the multinationalfirm based solely on economies of scale and transport costs cannot be satisfactory either.As described above,I will instead set forth a purely organizational,property-rights model of the multinationalfirm.My model will make no distinction betweenfirm-specific and plant-specific economies of scale. Furthermore,trade will be costless and factor prices will not differ across countries. Yet multinationals will emerge in equilibrium,and their implied intrafirm tradeflows will match the strong patterns identified above.This paper is also related to previous attempts to model the internalization deci-sion of multinationalsfirms.Following the insights from the seminal work of Casson (1979),Rugman(1981)and others,this literature has constructed models studying the role of informational asymmetries and knowledge non-excludability in determin-ing the choice between direct investment and licensing(e.g.,Ethier,1986,Ethier and Markusen,1996).Among other things,this paper differs from this literature in stressing the importance of capital intensity and the allocation of residual rights in the internalization decision,and perhaps more importantly,in describing and testing the implications of such a decision for the pattern of intrafirm trade.Finally,this paper is also related to an emerging literature on general-equilibrium models of industry structure(e.g.,McLaren,2000,Grossman and Helpman,2002a). My theoretical framework shares some features with the recent contribution by Gross-man and Helpman.In their model,however,the costs of transacting inside thefirm are introduced by having integrated suppliers incur exogenously higher variable costs (as in Williamson,1985).More importantly,theirs is a closed-economy model and therefore does not consider international trade in goods,which of course is central in my contribution.8The rest of the paper is organized as follows.Section2describes the closed-economy version of the model and studies the role of factor intensity in determining 8Although in this paper I show that a Grossman-Hart-Moore view of thefirm is consistent with the facts in Figures1and2,neither my theoretical model nor the available empirical evidence is rich enough to test this view of thefirm against alternative ones.This would be a major undertaking on its own.See Baker and Hubbard(2002)and Whinston(2002)for more formal treatments of these issues.the equilibrium mode of organization in a given industry.Section3describes the multi-country version of the model and discusses the international location of produc-tion as well as the implied patterns of intrafirm trade.Section4presents econometric evidence supporting the view that both capital intensity and capital abundance are significant factors in explaining the pattern of intrafirm U.S.imports.Section5con-cludes.The proofs of the main results are relegated to the Appendix.2The Closed-Economy Model:Ownership and Cap-ital IntensityThis section describes the closed-economy version of the model.In section3below,I will reinterpret the equilibrium of this closed economy as that of an integrated world economy.The features of this equilibrium will then be used to analyze the patterns of specialization and trade in a world in which the endowments of the integrated economy are divided up among countries.2.1Set-upEnvironment Consider a closed economy that employs two factors of production, capital and labor,to produce a continuum of varieties in two sectors,Y and Z. Capital and labor are inelastically supplied and freely mobile across sectors.The economy is inhabited by a unit measure of identical consumers that view the varieties in each industry as differentiated.In particular,letting y(i)and z(i)be consumption of variety i in sectors Y and Z,preferences of the representative consumer are of the formU=µZ n Y0y(i)αdi¶µαµZ n Z0z(i)αdi¶1−µα,(1) where n Y(n Z)is the endogenously determined measure of varieties in industry Y (Z).Consumers allocate a constant shareµ∈(0,1)of their spending in sector Y and a share1−µin sector Z.The elasticity of substitution between any two varieties in a given sector,1/(1−α),is assumed to be greater than one.Technology Goods are also differentiated in the eyes of producers.In particular, each variety y(i)requires a special and distinct intermediate input which I denote byx Y(i).Similarly,in sector Z,each variety z(i)requires a distinct component x Z(i). The specialized intermediate input must be of high quality,otherwise the output of thefinal good is zero.If the input is of high quality,production of thefinal good requires no further costs and y(i)=x Y(i)(or z(i)=x Z(i)in sector Z).Production of a high-quality intermediate input requires capital and labor.For simplicity,technology is assumed to be Cobb-Douglas:x k(i)=µK x,k(i)k¶βkµL x,k(i)k¶1−βk,k∈{Y,Z}(2) where K x,k(i)and L x,k(i)denote the amount of capital and labor employed in pro-duction of variety i in industry k∈{Y,Z}.I assume that industry Y is more capital-intensive than industry Z,i.e.1≥βY>βZ≥0.Low-quality intermediate inputs can be produced at a negligible cost in both sectors.There are alsofixed costs associated with the production of an intermediate in-put.For simplicity,it is assumed thatfixed costs in each industry have the same factor intensity as variable costs,so that the total cost functions are homothetic.In particular,fixed costs for each variety in industry k∈{Y,Z}are frβk w1−βk,where r is the rental rate of capital and w the wage rate.Firm structure There are two types of producers:final-good producers and sup-pliers of intermediate inputs.Before any investment is made,afinal-good producer decides whether it wants to enter a given market,and if so,whether to obtain the component from a vertically integrated supplier or from a stand-alone supplier.An integrated supplier is just a division of thefinal-good producer and thus has no con-trol rights over the amount of input produced.Figuratively,at any point in time the parentfirm could selectivelyfire the manager of the supplying division and seize production.Conversely,a stand-alone supplier does indeed have these residual rights of control.In Hart and Moore’s(1990)words,in such a case thefinal-good producer could only“fire”the entire supplyingfirm,including its production.Integrated and non-integrated suppliers differ only in the residual rights they are entitled to,and in particular both have access to the same technology as specified in(2).9 9This is in contrast with the transaction-cost literature that usually assumes that integration leads to an exogenous increase in variable costs(e.g.Williamson,1985,Grossman and Helpman,As discussed in the introduction,a premise of this paper is that investments in physical capital are easier to share than investments in labor input.To capture this idea,I assume that while the labor input is necessarily provided by the supplier,capital expenditures rK x,k (i )are instead transferable,in the sense that the final-good producer can decide whether to let the supplier incur this factor cost too,or rather rent the capital itself and hand it to the supplier at no charge.10Irrespective of who bears their cost,the investments in capital and labor are chosen simultaneously and non-cooperatively.11Once a final-good producer and its supplier enter the market,they are locked into the relationship:the investments rK x,k (i )and wL x,k (i )are incurred upon entry and are useless outside the relationship.In Williamson’s (1985)words,the initially competitive environment is fundamentally transformed into one of bilateral monopoly.Regardless of firm structure and the choice of cost sharing,fixed costs associated with production of the component are divided as follows:f F r βk w 1−βk for the final-good producer and f S r βk w 1−βk for the supplier,with f F +f S =f .12Free entry into each sector ensures zero expected pro fits for a potential entrant.To simplify the description of the industry equilibrium,I assume that upon entry the supplier makes a lump-sum transfer T k (i )to the final-good producer,which can vary by industry and variety.Ex-ante,there is a large number of identical,potential suppliers for each variety in each industry,so that competition among these suppliers 2002a).10Alternatively,one could assume that labor costs are also transferrable,but that their transfer leads to a signi ficant fall in productivity.This fall in productivity could be explained,in an interna-tional context,by the inability of multinational firms to cope with idiosyncratic labor markets (c.f.,Caves,1996,p.123).11The assumption that the final-good producer decides between bearing all or none of the capital expenditures can be relaxed to a case of partial transferability.For instance,imagine that x k (i )was produced according to:x k (i )=ÃK F x,k (i )βk !βk ÃK S x,k (i )η(βk )(1−βk )!η(βk )(1−βk )µL x,k (i )(1−η(βk ))(1−βk )¶(1−η(βk ))(1−βk )where K F x,k (i )represents the part of the capital input that is transferable,and where K S x,k (i )is inalieanable to the supplier.As long as the elasticity of output with respect to transferable capital is higher,the higher the capital intensity in production,the same qualitative results would go through.In particular,as long as βk +η(βk )(1−βk )increases with βk ,the model would still predict more integration in capital-intensive industries (see footnote 24).I follow the simpler speci fication in (2)because it greatly simpli fies the algebra of the general equilibrium.12Henceforth,I associate a subscript F with the final-good producer and a subscript S with the supplier.will make T k(i)adjust so as to make them break even.Thefinal-good producer chooses the mode of organization so as to maximize its ex-ante profits,which include the transfer.Contract Incompleteness The setting is one of incomplete contracts.In partic-ular,it is assumed that an outside party cannot distinguish between a high-quality and a low-quality intermediate input.Hence,input suppliers andfinal-good pro-ducers cannot sign enforceable contracts specifying the purchase of a certain type of intermediate input for a certain price.If they did,input suppliers would have an incentive to produce a low-quality input at the lower cost and still cash the same revenues.I take the existence of contract incompleteness as a fact of life,and will not complicate the model to relax the informational assumptions needed for this in-completeness to exist.13It is equally assumed that no outside party can verify the amount of ex-ante investments rK x,k(i)and wL x,k(i).If these were verifiable,then final-good producers and suppliers could contract on them,and the cost-reducing benefit of producing a low-quality input would disappear.For the same reason,it is assumed that the parties cannot write contracts contingent on the volume of sale revenues obtained when thefinal good is sold.Following Grossman and Hart(1986), the only contractibles ex-ante are the allocation of residual rights and the transfer T k(i)between the parties.14If the supplier incurs all variable costs,the contract incompleteness gives rise to a standard hold-up problem.Thefinal-good producer will want to renegotiate the price after x k(i)has been produced,since at this point the intermediate input is useless outside the relationship.Foreseeing this renegotiation,the input supplier will 13>From the work of Aghion,Dewatripont and Rey(1994),Nöldeke and Schmidt(1995)and others,it is well-known that allowing for specific-performance contracts can lead,under certain circumstances,to efficient ex-ante relationship-specific investments.Che and Hausch(1997)have shown,however,that when ex-ante investments are cooperative(in the sense,that one party’s invest-ment benefits the other party),specific-performance contracts may not lead tofirst-best investment levels and may actually have no value.14The assumption of non-contractibility of ex-ante investments could be relaxed to a case of partial contractibility.I have investigated an extension of the model in which production requires both contractible and non-contractible investments.If the marginal cost of non-contractible investments is increasing in the amount of contractible investments,the ability to set the contractible investments in the ex-ante contract is not sufficient to solve the underinvestment problem discussed below,and the model delivers results analogous to the ones discussed in the main text.。

泡棉知识

泡棉知识

泡棉特性一览表
PORON 聚氨酯 压缩变形 (室温/%) 压缩变形 (70℃/%) 释气 防腐蚀 (金属接触) 能量吸收 价格 2 <10 极低 极佳 极佳 较高
PE 10 43 极低 极佳 一般 极低
BISCO 硅胶 1 <5 极低 差 良好 极高
氯丁橡胶 3 28 高 差 一般 适中
三元乙丙 橡胶 3 28 高 差 一般 适中
包装、保温
IXPE
0.2~8mm
电子产品构造 缓冲
PEF
2~100mm
10/15/20/25/30/40
包装、五金
EPE
3~100mm
10/20/40
包装
LDPE
0.5~6mm
家电、仪表ຫໍສະໝຸດ 乙烯树脂 1 48 变化 差 极佳 中低
EVA 7 40 高 差 一般 极低
什么是聚氨酯(PU)泡棉?
1.聚氨酯泡棉的定义
聚氨酯泡棉又称聚氨酯弹性体,他属于特种合成橡胶,在分子链中含有较多氨 基甲酸的弹性聚合物。
2.PORON的特性
①弹性体 ②热固性 ③中等至高密度(190-480kg/cm2) ④片状涂覆(0.25mm~12.7mm/较薄材料需要PET基材)
泡棉材料知识
泡棉的分类
1.按材质分类: PE(聚乙烯)泡棉 PU(聚氨酯)泡棉 EVA泡棉 泡棉 硅泡棉
NITTO-SCF100/SCF200 ROGERS-PORON;PSR-PORON;RIC-PORON
氯丁橡胶
三元乙丙橡胶 乙烯树脂
2.按结构分类:
开孔(孔泡与孔泡相互连通)
泡棉 闭孔(孔泡与孔泡互不连通)
聚氨酯(PU)泡棉
PE泡棉的分类
XPE(化学交联发泡)

热烈祝贺叶荫宇教授获得冯·诺依曼理论奖

热烈祝贺叶荫宇教授获得冯·诺依曼理论奖

热烈祝贺叶荫宇教授获得冯·诺依曼理论奖2009年10月11日斯坦福大学的叶荫宇教授被授予冯·诺依曼理论奖,此次获奖是华人第一次获得该奖项。

叶荫宇教授1982年在华中科技大学获自动控制系统与控制专业学士学位;1983年在斯坦福大学获得工程经济系统硕士学位;1988年获得斯坦福大学工程经济系统和运筹学博士学位。

2002年回到斯坦福大学担任终身教授。

INFORMS的冯·诺依曼理论奖创建于1975年,每年颁发一次,奖励给在运筹学和管理科学领域做出奠基性的,有深远影响力贡献的一名科学家或一个研究群体。

该奖是奖励能够经受时间检验的一批学术成果,评判标准包括重要性,创新性,深度,和科学性。

第一位获奖者是线性规划之父George B. Dantzig教授。

获奖者中,既有诺贝尔经济学奖获得者,也有众多计算机科学、控制论等领域的创始人。

叶荫宇教授一直非常关心国内运筹学的发展,多次回国讲学并做系列学术讲座。

中国运筹学会感谢叶荫宇教授的长期支持,并热烈祝贺叶荫宇教授获得冯·诺依曼理论奖!附一:叶荫宇教授的获奖演说。

附二:冯·诺依曼理论奖的历年获得者。

List of recipients2009 Y urii Nesterov and Y inyu Y e2008 Frank Kelly2007 Arthur F. Veinott, Jr. for his profound contributions to three major areas of operations research and management science: inventory theory, d ynamic programming and lattice programming.2006 Martin Grötschel, LászlóLovász and Alexander Schrijver for their fundamental path-breaking work in combinatorial optimization.2005 Robert J. Aumann in recognition of his fundamental contributions to game theory and related areas2004 J. Michael Harrison for his profound contributions to two major areas of operations research and management science: stochastic networks and mathematical finance.2003 Arkadi Nemirovski and Michael J. T odd for their seminal and profound contributions in continuous optimization.2002 Donald L. Iglehart and Cyrus Derman for their fundamental contributions to performance analysis and optimization of stochastic systems2001 Ward Whitt for his contributions to queueing theory, applied probability and stochastic modelling2000 Ellis L. Johnson and Manfred W. Padberg1999 R. Tyrrell Rockafellar1998 Fred W. Glover1997 Peter Whittle1996 Peter C. Fishburn1995 Egon Balas1994 Lajos T akacs1993 Robert Herman1992 Alan J. Hoffman and Philip Wolfe1991 Barlow, Proschan1990 Richard Karp1989 Harry M. Markowitz1988 Herbert Simon1987 Samuel Karlin1986 Kenneth J. Arrow1985 Jack Edmonds1984 Ralph Gomory1983 Herbert E. Scarf1982 Abraham Charnes, William W. Cooper, and Richard J. Duffin 1981 Lloyd Shapley1980 David Gale, Harold W. Kuhn, and Albert W. Tucker1979 David Blackwell1978 John F. Nash and Carlton E. Lemke1977 Felix Pollaczek1976 Richard Bellman1975 George B. Dantzig for his work on linear programming。

Grant_and_Lee_A_study_in_contrasts

Grant_and_Lee_A_study_in_contrasts

Grant?and?Lee: A?study?in?contrasts 格兰特和李:对比研究1865年4月9,格兰特和李在非吉尼亚阿波托克斯的一间普通的会客厅里达成协议:非吉尼亚北部李的军队投降,这意味着在美国历史上一个伟大的篇章宣布结束,进而一个新的伟大篇章将拉开序幕。

这些人将美国内战推向了终点。

诚然,还有一些军队在负隅抵抗。

在接下来的一段日子里,逃亡的南部联邦政府试图寻找再生力量,结果都是徒劳的。

因为主力部队已经被消亡了。

事实上格兰特和李在签署文件时一切就已经宣告结束了。

他们达成协议的那个小房间却成了美国历史上极为辛酸和富有戏剧性的一幕。

他们都是很强的人,他们属于不同的团体,代表两个对抗的利益。

他们俩成了成败的关键。

罗伯特.E.李代表的是旧的民族势力,在某种程度上也可能成为美国历史上的统治者。

李生于非吉尼亚的海滨地区,家庭,文化和传统等联系起来构成他的背景。

他所处的时代正是由骑士时代向新世纪时代转变的时代,人们开始写自己的故事和神话而不再崇拜骑士。

他代表了来源骑士和英国乡绅时代的生活方式。

美国是一块完全重新开始的大陆,建立在众生平等、机会平等这个简单而又朦胧的理念上。

在这片大地上李却有这样的想法:在社会结构上有一种明显的不平等,在某种程度上对社会有益。

应该有悠闲地阶层,他们受土地拥有者的支持。

反过来,社会也会以土地作为它财富的主要来源。

必须带来这样的结果(根据他的想法):他们对社会有着强烈的责任感,人们不再是为自己谋利益而是为了那份庄严地义务。

这份义务附加在他们身上为他们带来了好处。

从他们当中将会产生国家领导人。

对于他们国家将能够追求更高的价值-在思想,行为及个人举止上,从而赋予这个国家力量和美德。

李具有这种贵族理想中的最高成分。

通过他,拥有土地的贵族能证明自己是正当的。

四年来联邦政府曾发动一场战争来支持李。

最后,联邦政府看起来像是为李而战斗,好像李本身就代表了南部联邦……联邦政府所支持的生活方式可能永远提供的都是最好的,在阿波之前他成为传奇人物。

重复测量方差分析报告模板

重复测量方差分析报告模板

18
7
116
98
18
8
138
122
16
9
126
108
18
10
124
106
18
前后测量设计的统计方法
• 前提条件:在假定测量时间对观测结果没有
影响时,才能推断处理是否有效。
• 统计方法:用配对 t 检验或配对秩和检验 • 高血压患者治疗前后的舒张压平均下降了
16mmHg。
经配对t检验,t =16.18, P=0.000
差值
编号 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20
对照组 前后 118 124 132 122 134 132 114 96 118 124 128 118 118 116 132 122 120 124 134 128
差值
确定疗效的前后测量设计必须增 加平行对照
• 平行对照:处理组和对照组的受试对象
333.800
df 1
1.000 1.000 1.000
1 1.000 1.000 1.000
18 18.000 18.000 18.000
Mean Square 1020.100 1020.100 1020.100 1020.100 348.100 348.100 348.100 348.100 18.544 18.544 18.544 18.544
124.8
后 124 122 132 96 124 118 116 122 124 128 120.6
可以分析:
• 时间主效应:治疗前、后的舒张压均数是
否不同?
• 组间主效应:处理组与对照组的舒张压均
数是否不同?
• 交互作用:组间的舒张压均数差异是否随
  1. 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
  2. 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
  3. 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。

密度 in pcf
9.4 pcf 12.5 pcf 15 pcf 20 pcf 25 pcf 30 pcf 43.8 pcf
4790-92-25
• Ex2:
SR – S – 40 P –
厚度 (metric)
0.5t – 0.5 mm thick
0.5t
厚度 (inch)
0.021
4790-92-25021-04 P

25
40 15 20 50 15 20 MHML-
40
24 32 24 32
LTL-
40
24 32
H-
24 32
30
60 15 20 25
48
48
HH-
48
FHMX-
48
48HF

PORON 対照表
Rogers Code 4790-92 15 20 25 SR-S RIC SR-S Grades 15P 24P 32P 40P
SS-24P/32P:超软等级,各種高.低温度對應性更強
Very Popular for Handheld Electronics Products !!
PORON 對照表
Rogers Code 4701 30 15 20 LO/FR Grade MS24 32 RIC Original Grade LE20
4790-92
• Ex2:
SR – S –
密度 (metric)
15 – 150 kg/m3 20 – 200 kg/m3 24 – 240 kg/m3 32 – 320 kg/m3 40 – 400 kg/m3 48 – 480 kg/m3 70 – 700 kg/m3
40 P – 0.5t
P: 附 PET 基材
• LO/FR (阻燃)規格:
MS(30), ML(40), MH(50)
• 原配方: HH , FH , MO, MX, ASRS, SRU, SS, SSA, LF/HF Coating
RIC PORON – 機脚系列
等級 :
(M)H-32 適合用以一般緩沖材用途 (M)H-48(C) 適合用以標準脚塾 HH- 48(C) FH- 48(C) MO-48(C) 能負荷重的機械不変形 能耐更高的負荷 和 HH48C 的硬度相等、及取得 UL94 HBF
50 (RIC Original) 60
(RIC Original) (RIC Original)
• Ex1:
ML –
密度 (metric)
15 – 150 kg/m3 20 – 200 kg/m3 24 – 240 kg/m3 32 – 320 kg/m3 40 – 400 kg/m3 48 – 480 kg/m3 70 – 700 kg/m3
配方
密度 厚度
4701
工業用
40
20
059
04
標準顔色
• Ex2:
SR – S – 40 P – 0C Original) (RIC Original) (RIC Original)
SR-S: 慢回弾 ASRS: 防静電 SRS SR-U: SR UL94HBF規格 SS: 超軟
RIC 産品 産品介紹
• 例: ML-32-1.5t SR-S-40P-0.5t
• Ex1:
ML – 32 – 1.5t
HPF 產品對應
30 40
配方
LE: Low Modulus with Elongation MS: Soft 軟 ML – Low Modulus (M = Mega material) MH – High Modulus HH – Harder than H-formulation FH – Far Hard MX – EXtra Hard
RIC 的介紹
誰是 RIC?
50% 50%
Who is RIC?
•1984 成立 •工場位置:名古屋 (#1), 三重(#2) – 日本, 及 蘇州(#3) – 中国 (RIS Rogers Inoac Suzhou Corp) •員工:80人 (其中. 32名 臨時員工) •生産線:
• 取得認証: ISO-9001 & ISO-14001
Popular for Electronics & Handsets Products !!
RIC PORON – PET 基材系列
等级:
SR-S(92) – 15P/24P/32P/40P/48P/70P:慢回弹,柔软 ASRS – 24PA/32PA/40PA/48PA:SR-S 具防静电功能 SR-U-40P:SR-S 符合 UL94 HBF
• Ex2:
P: PET 基材
SR – S – 40 P – 0.5t
配方
密度 厚度
4790
工業用
92
25
021
04
標準顔色
RIC PORON – 各種規格

SS<SRS<LE < L(U) < H< HH (MO) < FH<MX 有各種規格供選択

• 標準規格:
L(01), H(05), U, LE/LT
MX- 48(HF) 適合以脚塾、最硬型、表面特別高摩擦処理
RIC PORON – LO/FR 系列
等級 :
MS(30) - 24/32/40 ML(40) - 24/32 MH(50) - 24/32/48
• 低揮発気体 • 耐燃型、不含鹵素、無代奥辛材料 (UL94 HBF)等級。
•厚度 : 0.3 ~ 10.0 mm
32 – 1.5t
密度 in pcf
9.4 pcf 12.5 pcf 15 pcf 20 pcf 25 pcf 30 pcf 43.8 pcf
• Ex1:
ML – 32 –
1.5t
厚度 (inch)
0.059
厚度 (metric)
1.5t – 1.5 mm thick
• Ex1:
ML – 32 – 1.5t
厚度 :
最低従 0.2mm
~ 3.0 mm
30
-
48P
70P
• 提供不同種類產品以增加你們的銷售量 • 羅傑斯亞洲區所有辦事處可提供所有 RIC 產品 (包括報價及交貨期) • 沒有限制你提供模切或銷售RIC材料給任何客戶 • 相配產品包括 : 腳垫, 更薄 (SRS) 空間填充材料 • 謝謝!
相关文档
最新文档