外商直接投资怎样影响经济的增长外文翻译

合集下载
  1. 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
  2. 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
  3. 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。

本科毕业论文外文翻译
外文题目:How does foreign direct investment affect economic growth 出处:Journal of International Economics 45(1998) 115-135
作者: E.Borensztein,J.De Gregorio,J-W.Lee
How does foreign direct investment affect economic
growth?
Abstract
We test the effect of foreign direct investment (FDI) on economic growth in a cross-country regression framework, utilizing data on FDI flows from industrial countries to 69 developing countries over the last two decades. Our results suggest that FDI is an important vehicle for the transfer of technology, contributing relatively more to growth than domestic investment. However, the higher productivity of FDI holds only when the host country has a minimum threshold stock of human capital. Thus, FDI contributes to economic growth only when a sufficient absorptive capability of the advanced technologies is available in the host economy.
一、Introduction
Technology diffusion plays a central role in the process of economic development. In contrast to the traditional growth framework, where technological change was left as an unexplained residual, the recent growth literature has highlighted the dependence of growth rates on the state of domestic technology relative to that of the rest of the world. Thus, growth rates in developing countries are, in part, explained by a ‘catch-up’ process in the level of technology. In a typical model of technology diffusion, the rate of economic growth of a backward country
depends on the extent of adoption and implementation of new technologies that are already in use in leading countries.
Technology diffusion can take place through a variety of channels that involve the transmission of ideas and new technologies. Imports of high-technology products, adoption of foreign technology and acquisition of human capital through various means are certainly important conduits for the international diffusion of technology. Besides these channels, foreign direct investment by multinational corporations (MNCs) is considered to be a major channel for the access to advanced technologies by developing countries. MNCs are among the most technologically advanced firms, accounting for a substantial part of the world’s research and development (R and D) investment. Some recent work on economic growth has highlighted the role of foreign direct investment in the technological progress of developing countries. Findlay (1978) postulates that foreign direct investment increases the rate of technical progress in the host country through a ‘contagion’ effect from the more advanced technology, management practices, etc. used by the foreign firms.Wang (1990) incorporates this idea into a model more in line with the neoclassical growth framework, by assuming that the increase in ‘knowledge’ applied to production is determined as a function of foreign direct investment (FDI).
The purpose of this paper is to examine empirically the role of FDI in the process of technology diffusion and economic growth in developing countries.We motivate the empirical work by a model of endogenous growth, in which the rate of technological progress is the main determinant of the long-term growth rate of income. Technological progress takes place through a process of ‘capital deepening’in the form of the introduction of new varieties of capital goods. MNCs possess more advanced ‘knowledge’, which allows them to introduce new capital goods at lower cost. However, the application of this more advanced technologies also requires the presence of a sufficient level of human capital in the host economy. The stock of human capital in the host country, therefore, limits the absorptive capability of a developing country, as in Nelson and Phelps (1966), and Benhabib and Spiegel (1994). Hence, the model highlights the roles of both the introduction of more advanced technology and the requirement of absorptive capability in the host country as
determinants of economic growth, and suggests the empirical investigation of the complementarity between FDI and human capital in the process of productivity growth.
We test the effect of FDI on economic growth in a framework of cross-country regressions utilizing data on FDI flows from industrial countries to 69 developing countries over the last two decades. Our results suggest that FDI is in fact an important vehicle for the transfer of technology, contributing to growth in larger measure than domestic investment. Moreover, we find that there is a strong complementary effect between FDI and human capital, that is, the contribution of FDI to economic growth is enhanced by its interaction with the level of human capital in the host country. However, our empirical results imply that FDI is more productive than domestic investment only when the host country has a minimum threshold stock of human capital. The results are robust to a number of alternative specifications, which control for the variables usually identified as the main determinants of economic growth in cross-country regressions. This sensitivity analysis along the lines of Levine and Renelt (1992) shows a robust relationship between economic growth, FDI and human capital.
We also investigate the effect of FDI on domestic investment, namely, whether there is evidence that the inflow of foreign capital ‘crowds out’ domestic investment. In principle, this effect could have either sign: by competing in product and financial markets MNCs may displace domestic firms; conversely, FDI may support the expansion of domestic firms by complementarity in production or by increasing productivity through the spillover of advanced technology. Our results are supportive of a crowding-in effect, that is, a one-dollar increase in the net inflow of FDI is associated with an increase in total investment in the host economy of more than one dollar, but do not appear to be very robust.
Thus, it appears that the main channel through which FDI contributes to economic growth is by stimulating technological progress, rather than by increasing total capital accumulation in the host economy.
二、Data
There are several sources for data on foreign direct investment. Two IMF publications provide data on net and gross foreign direct investment (International Financial Statistics, and Balance of Payments Statistics, respectively). Net FDI refers to inflows net of outflows, and gross FDI refers only to inflows, that is, foreign direct investment into the country. An OECD publication (Geographical Distribution of Financial Flows to Developing Countries) tallies gross FDI originated in OECD member countries into developing economies. The choice between these alternatives depends on which data set would correspond more closely to the FDI effect we are trying to uncover.
In the first place, it seems more appropriate to use gross data because we are interested in the effects of foreign direct investment in the host country via transfer of knowledge and other spillover effects; in addition, we would not expect the outflow of foreign direct investment to involve a similar negative growth effects for the source country (loss of knowledge). In the second place, in our framework, foreign direct investment flows from industrialized to developing countries to close the technological gap. Foreign direct investment taking place between countries with roughly the same level of technological development may respond to a large extent to other factors, including global firm strategy and market penetration, or to allow firms to circumvent trade restrictions and offset other advantages accorded to domestic producers. This type of foreign direct investment flows may not be expected to display higher than average productivity. For this reason we focus only on foreign direct investment received by developing countries. And furthermore, since flows of foreign direct investment between developing countries may also respond to factors other than the technological gap, we also exclude those flows.
Therefore, the OECD measure of foreign direct investment, while having a partial coverage, appears to be the most appropriate for our purposes. These data are available on a yearly basis from 1970. National accounts data, such as the growth rate of income, initial income and government consumption, are all taken from Summers and Heston (release 5.5 of June 1993) which provides data up to 1989. This allows us to consider a 20-year period for the empirical investigation. The growth rate measure
is the average annual rate of per capita real GDP over each decade, 1970–79 and 1980–89. Government consumption is measured by the average share of real government consumption in real GDP.
For the human capital stock variable we use the initial-year level of average years of the male secondary schooling constructed by Barro and Lee (1993). According to Barro and Lee (1994), this measure of educational attainment is the one most significantly correlated with growth. Data for the other explanatory variables, such as the domestic investment rate, the foreign exchange parallel market premium and the measures of political instability and financial development are also taken from Barro and Lee (1994).
三、Conclusions
There is a good a priori case to presume that FDI is more productive than domestic investment. As Graham and Krugman (1991) argue, domestic firms have better knowledge and access to domestic markets; if a foreign firm decides to enter the market, it must compensate for the advantages enjoyed by domestic firms. It is most likely that a foreign firm that decides to invest in another country enjoys
lower costs and higher productive efficiency than its domestic competitors. In the case of developing countries in particular, it is likely that the higher efficiency of
FDI would result from a combination of advanced management skills and more modern technology; FDI may be the main channel through which advanced technology is transferred to developing countries.
Different types of economic distortions, however, may jeopardize the role of FDI as a means for advanced technology transfer. For example, because of protectionist trade policies, FDI may be the only way to gain access to domestic markets by firms that would otherwise have been exporters to the host country. Similarly, governments may offer a set of incentives to foreign investors to stimulate the inflow of FDI, with the objective of increasing foreign exchange reserves or of developing certain sectors considered strategic from an industrial
policy viewpoint. These policies may result in a flow of FDI that does not respond
to higher efficiency but only to profit opportunities created by distorted incentives. These considerations make the empirical evaluation of the performance of FDI an appealing question. We investigated these issues in a sample that comprises FDI flows from industrial country into developing countries
The most robust finding of this paper is that the effect of FDI on economic growth is dependent on the level of human capital available in the host economy. There is a strong positive interaction between FDI and the level of educational attainment (our proxy for human capital). Notably, the same interaction is not significant in the case of domestic investment, possibly a reflection of differences of technological nature between FDI and domestic investment. We also found some evidence of a crowding-in effect, namely that FDI is complementary to domestic investment. This effect, however, seems to be less robust than our other findings.
Some caution must be exercised, however, in the interpretation of the size of the effect on economic growth of FDI. Our data measures the international flow of resources for foreign direct investment, as recorded in balance of payments statistics. This is, however, only part of the resources invested by a multinational firm, because some part of the investment may be financed through debt or equity issues raised in the domestic market. Thus, our measure of FDI underestimates the total value of fixed investment made by a multinational firm and the coefficients on FDI may be proportionally overestimated. To the extent that this bias in the measure of FDI is uniform across countries and over time, the qualitative results are not affected.
Finally, the results of this paper suggest some directions for further research. The results suggest that the beneficial effects on growth of FDI come through higher efficiency rather than simply from higher capital accumulation. This suggests the possibility of testing the effect of FDI on the rate of total factor productivity growth in recipient countries. In addition, given the robustness of the effect of interactions between human capital and FDI, it might be interesting to explore the effects of FDI on the level of human capital. As we have argued above, FDI is a vehicle for the adoption of new technologies, and therefore, the training required to prepare the labour force to work with new technologies suggests that there may also be an effect
有几个外商直接投资的数据来源,国际货币基金组织出版物提供两个净外国直接投资和总(分别是国际金融统计和国际收支平衡统计)的数据。

净FDI是指流入量出去流出量,而毛FDI只是指流入量,那就是外商直接投资进入该国。

经合组织的出版物(地方金融流动分布在发展中国家)的外国直接投资总额相符经合组织成员国的起源到发展中经济体。

这些替代品之间的选择取决于所对应的数据集与我们正努力去发掘的外国直接投资的效果关系更加密切。

首先,它似乎更合适使用总的数据,因为我们感兴趣的是东道国的外国直接投资的影响,通过转移知识和溢出效应等,此外,我们也不会期望外国直接投资流出涉及类似的负增长效应在来源国(知识流失)。

其次,在我们的框架里,外商直接投资的流向是为了消除发达国家到发展中国家的技术差距。

外商直接投资在国与国之间发生,在很大程度上科技发展水平相似的国家对其他要素的反应大致相同,包括跨国公司战略和市场占有率,或者允许公司规避贸易抵制,以及其他的给予国内生产者的一些优惠。

这种类型的外商直接投资的流动不要求高于平均生产率。

由于这个原因,我们仅仅关注于从发达国家来的外商直接投资。

另外,我们不包括发展中国家间的外商直接投资流动,因为可能有其他因素导致的技术差距。

因此,经济合作与发展组织针对外商直接投资的措施,虽然有部分重复,但是很明显是最合适我们的目的的。

这些数据很适合从1970年开始的每年的基础上。

国民经济核算数据,如收入的增长率,初始收入和政府消费都是从萨姆斯和赫斯顿(1993.6)提供的直到1989年的数据。

这允许我们考虑一个为期20年的实证调查。

增长率的测量的方法是每十年的国内生产总值的平均年增长率:1970—1979和1980—1989.政府消费的测量是基于真实政府消费者真实GDP的平均份额来的。

由于人力资源存量的可变性我们使用初始水平下的平均年份由本和李(1993)总结。

根据本和李(1994)的总结,这个措施是教育程度的一个最显著的相关增长。

其他数据的解释变量,如:国内投资的增长,外汇平行市场的升水和政局不稳定的措施。

同时金融的发展也是根据本和李(1994)的。

三、总结
有一个很好的先例表明FDI比国内投资更富有成效。

格雷厄姆和克鲁曼(1991)认为,国内公司对于国内市场更了解,更加能够进入。

如果一个外国公司决定进入这个市场,它必须补偿国内公司所享有的优势。

当一个外国公司决定投资另一个国家时,它将比它的国内竞争者享有更低的成本和更高的生产效率。

就对于特殊的发展中国家来说,高效率的外商直接投资很可能使先进的管理技能和更现代化的技术互相结合。

是先进的技术转移到发展中国家的主要的途径。

不同类型的经济变形,无论如何,都有可能危害到外商直接投资作为先进技术转移的一种方法的作用。

举个例子来说,由于贸易保护政策,外商直接投资对于那些出口商来说可能是增加进入国内市场机会的唯一的方法。

同样,政府可能会提供一系列的激励政策来刺激外国投资者增加外商直接投资的流入,以外汇储备增加以及发展一些从战略上考虑产业政策的部门作为目标。

这些政策可能导致外商直接投资的流通不能高效率而仅仅能获利。

这些因素使外商直接投资的表现的实证评价成为一个吸引人的问题。

我们通过分析外商直接投资如何从发达国家进入发展中国家来研究这些问题。

这篇文章最大的发现是外商直接投资对经济增长的影响取决于在主体经济中可利用的人力资本水平。

外商直接投资跟教育程度的水平之间有强烈的积极互动关系。

特别是,同样的作用在国内投资是不显著的,可能在外商直接投资跟国内投资之间有一种不同的自然技术反映。

我们也发现了聚集效应的一些相关依据,也就是国内投资跟外商直接投资是互补的。

这个结果,无论如何,跟我们其他的发现相比没那么完善。

但是在解释外商直接投资对经济增长的规模效应时,有一些地方必须注意的。

我们计算了外商直接投资的国际资源流通的数据,并且作为保持国际收支平衡的记录。

然而,只是计算由跨国公司投入的资源部分,因为一些投资很可能是由在国内的债务或股票所提供的。

因此,我们对外商直接投资的计算低估了由跨国公司和比例估计过高的外商直接投资利用系数所组成的固定资本总值。

在一定程度上,外商直接投资数据会随着不同的国家和时间的推移而产生偏差,但本质上的结果不会受到影响。

总的来说,本文的结论为进一步的研究提供了一些方向。

研究结果表明来自于高效率的外商直接投资比简单的高效率的资本积累更加有益。

这个结果表明在容易接受的国家检测外商直接投资的增长率的全要素生产力的增长更加有效。

此外,人力资源和外商直接投资给出强有力的有效的相互作用,将会引起研究外商
直接投资对人力资源水平的影响的兴趣。

正如我们在上面所说的,外商直接投资是一个接收新技术的媒介,说明外商直接投资也有可能影响人力资源的积累,要求训练拥有新技术的劳动力。

相关文档
最新文档