测量中国的农产品出口的食品安全标准的影响【外文翻译】

合集下载

农产品出口数据与质量检验标准

农产品出口数据与质量检验标准

农产品出口数据与质量检验标准随着全球化的发展,农产品出口在国际贸易中扮演着重要的角色。

然而,农产品的质量问题一直是制约农产品出口的重要因素之一。

为了确保农产品出口的质量和安全,各国都制定了相应的质量检验标准。

本文将探讨农产品出口数据与质量检验标准之间的关系,并分析其对农产品出口的影响。

一、农产品出口数据的重要性农产品出口数据是指农产品出口的数量和金额等相关信息。

这些数据对于了解农产品出口的规模和趋势具有重要意义。

首先,农产品出口数据可以反映一个国家或地区的农业生产能力和竞争力。

通过分析农产品出口数据,可以了解到不同国家或地区的农业发展水平和农产品质量。

其次,农产品出口数据对于制定农业政策和农产品市场预测也具有重要参考价值。

通过分析农产品出口数据,政府可以及时调整农业政策,提高农产品出口的竞争力。

此外,农产品出口数据还可以为农产品贸易谈判提供依据,帮助国家争取更有利的贸易条件。

二、质量检验标准的意义质量检验标准是指对农产品质量进行检验和评估的标准。

质量检验标准的制定旨在保障农产品的质量和安全,防止低质量农产品进入市场。

质量检验标准可以从多个方面对农产品进行评估,包括农产品的外观、口感、营养成分、农药残留等。

通过质量检验标准,可以确保农产品符合国际贸易的要求,提高农产品的市场竞争力。

此外,质量检验标准还可以保护消费者的权益,确保他们购买到安全、健康的农产品。

三、农产品出口数据与质量检验标准的关系农产品出口数据与质量检验标准之间存在着密切的关系。

首先,农产品出口数据可以反映农产品的质量水平。

如果一个国家或地区的农产品出口数据持续增长,说明其农产品质量较高,受到国际市场的认可。

相反,如果农产品出口数据下降,可能意味着该国或地区的农产品质量存在问题,需要加强质量检验和监管。

其次,质量检验标准可以影响农产品出口数据。

如果一个国家或地区的质量检验标准过于严格,可能会导致农产品出口量减少。

因为农产品需要符合质量检验标准才能出口,如果标准过高,可能会增加农产品出口的难度。

食品安全与卫生标准对果品出口的影响

食品安全与卫生标准对果品出口的影响

食品安全与卫生标准对果品出口的影响目录一、食品安全与卫生标准的严格要求 (2)二、主要果品出口国及其市场份额 (5)三、果品加工与增值产品的市场潜力 (7)四、果品出口的主要品种与地区分布 (10)五、果品出口市场的总体规模与增长趋势 (14)随着现代生活方式的改变和饮食结构的调整,消费者对健康和环保的重视程度不断提高。

绿色果品和有机果品因其安全、健康、环保的特点,满足了消费者对高品质生活的追求,成为越来越多家庭的首选。

绿色果品与有机果品的兴起为果品出口市场带来了新的机遇和挑战。

为了抓住机遇、应对挑战,出口企业应积极提升产品质量和附加值,加强品牌建设和市场推广,同时密切关注国际贸易动态和政策变化,灵活调整出口策略和市场布局。

各国政府纷纷出台支持有机农业的政策,如减免税款、提供资金和技术支持等,推动有机食品市场的扩大。

在中国,政府也积极推动绿色果品和有机果品的发展,通过加强农产品质量安全管理、提高农产品附加值等方式,提升中国农产品在国际市场上的地位和影响力。

声明:本文内容来源于公开渠道或根据行业大模型生成,对文中内容的准确性不作任何保证。

本文内容仅供参考,不构成相关领域的建议和依据。

一、食品安全与卫生标准的严格要求(一)国际食品安全与卫生标准概述1、食品安全与卫生标准的国际框架在果品出口市场中,食品安全与卫生标准受到严格监管,这主要基于一系列国际协议和组织,如世界卫生组织(WHO)、联合国粮农组织(FAO)以及世界贸易组织(WTO)等。

这些机构制定了多项关于食品安全与卫生的国际标准和指南,旨在确保全球食品贸易中的产品质量和消费者健康。

2、主要进口国的特定要求不同国家和地区对进口果品的安全与卫生标准有所不同,但普遍遵循一些核心原则,如农药残留限量、微生物污染控制、重金属及有害化学物质含量限制等。

例如,欧盟、美国和日本等发达国家对进口果品的检验标准尤为严格,要求提供详细的产地证明、农药使用记录及残留检测报告等。

外文翻译--中国主要农产品的显性比较优势及竞争力分析

外文翻译--中国主要农产品的显性比较优势及竞争力分析

中文2479字Revealed comparative advantage and competitiveness of China’sagricultural productsZhan JingEconomy and Management Collage, Nanhua University, Hengyang,4210100, China中国主要农产品的显性比较优势及竞争力分析詹晶(南华大学经济管理学院,湖南衡阳,421001)译文正文:中国主要农产品的显性比较优势及竞争力分析詹晶(南华大学经济管理学院,湖南衡阳,421001)摘要:本文在大量数据的基础上测算了1980-2003年期间中国部分农产品的显性比较优势指数及其比较竞争力。

测算结果表明中国在可食用蔬菜、茶叶等农产品上仍然具有比较优势,但是24 年来中国农产品的显性比较优势指数呈现下降趋势。

关键词:农产品; 国际贸易; 显性比较优势(RCA); 竞争力中国的农产品出口,为增加外汇、就业机会及城乡居民收入做出了重大贡献。

2003年农产品贸易余额为2.5美元亿美元,占外贸顺差总额的9.8%。

诚(2003)报道,由农产品出口可直接和间接创造19.88个就业机会。

巴拉萨(1965)在全球层面上首次提出了中国农产品的相对竞争力可以通过显示性比较优势分析(RCA),这对意识到中国农产品的竞争地位有作用的。

显示性比较优势的公式有某些类型的测量方法可以判定一个产业的竞争力,其中RCA指数就是重要的一个,RCA的概念基于的是传统的贸易理论。

原来的RCA指数,由巴拉萨(1965),可以被定义为:RCA= (X ij /X it) / (X nj / X nt)其中x表示出口,i代表一个国家,j是一种商品,x ij表示i国用来出口商品j。

t代表一组商品和n代表一组国家。

因此,该方程分析一个国家的出口占世界出口的商品与该国的出口总额占世界出口总额。

如果i国家j商品的世界出口份额,占i国的所有产品的世界出口份额越大,RCA将越大于1,这表明一个国家在生产特定商品上有一个“显性”比较优势。

食品安全问题对农产品出口的影响与控制

食品安全问题对农产品出口的影响与控制

食品安全问题对农产品出口的影响与控制近年来,食品安全问题逐渐引起人们的广泛关注和重视。

食品安全问题不仅对人体健康造成威胁,同时也对农产品出口带来了巨大的影响。

本文将探讨食品安全问题对农产品出口的影响,并提出相应的控制措施。

一、食品安全问题对农产品出口的影响1. 影响农产品出口量和价值食品安全问题的暴露会严重损害农产品的信誉和声誉,导致国外消费者对农产品的购买意愿大幅减弱。

一旦农产品失去了国外市场,不仅出口量会减少,还会导致农产品价格下跌,给农民带来巨大的经济损失。

2. 扰乱农产品贸易秩序食品安全问题会扰乱农产品贸易秩序,引发国际贸易纠纷。

一旦农产品出现安全问题,进口国可能会实施贸易限制措施,如禁止进口、增加检验检疫要求等。

这不仅对农产品出口国造成直接影响,还会使得国际贸易环境动荡不安,进而对全球农产品市场产生负面影响。

3. 损害国家形象和国际声誉食品安全问题的出现会对农产品出口国家形象和国际声誉造成严重损害,降低国家的软实力和竞争力。

国际社会普遍认为,一个国家的食品安全水平是衡量其经济、科技和管理水平的重要标志。

因此,食品安全问题会影响国家在国际舞台上的地位和影响力。

二、食品安全问题的控制措施1. 加强立法和监管农产品出口国应加强相关食品安全立法,完善食品安全监管体系。

制定严格的食品安全标准和质量监督制度,并加强对农产品生产、加工和销售环节的监测和检查,严惩违法行为,提高食品安全保障水平。

2. 推进农产品质量安全追溯体系建设建立健全农产品质量安全追溯体系,对农产品的生产、加工、流通等环节进行全程监控和追溯。

通过追溯体系,可以快速发现和追踪食品安全问题的源头,从而及时采取措施防止问题扩大,并保护农产品出口市场的信誉。

3. 提升农产品质量安全认证水平加强农产品质量安全认证工作,提升农产品质量和安全水平。

推广和普及国家认可的农产品质量认证体系,鼓励农业生产者通过认证体系认证,提高农产品出口的竞争力。

4. 强化信息公开与沟通合作加强食品安全信息的公开、透明和及时性,向国内外消费者提供真实、准确的农产品安全信息。

山东农产品出口贸易的影响因素及对策外文翻译修改稿

山东农产品出口贸易的影响因素及对策外文翻译修改稿

毕业设计(论文)外文翻译题目:影响中国的人民币汇率变动对农产品出口的影响:出口到日本的案例研究英文题目:The Effect of China's RMB Exchange RateMovement on Its Agricultural Export: A CaseStudy of Export to Japan系别:专业:班级:学号:姓名:指导老师:填表日期:影响中国的人民币汇率变动对农产品出口的影响:出口到日本的案例研究Longjiang Chen摘要本文试图考察变化和波动之间的关系来分析中国的人民币汇率和其农业出口。

建立了一个模型来分析人民币汇率影响农产品出口所面临两个运动约束包括中国特定的汇率制度和存在技术性贸易壁垒的农业贸易。

该模型表明,民币汇率的影响运动依赖汇率水平的比较(升值或折旧)效应和汇率风险的效果。

以中国农产品出口日本为例,实证检验以中国对日本农产品出口为例,进行了实证检验。

一个模型(1,1)指定衡量汇率波动和日常生活的回归与结构打破虚拟变量估计基于单位根检验结果与结构。

结果表明人民币兑日元升值将促进出口增长,与积极汇率波动促进农产品出口到日本而阻碍出口。

然而,汇率波动对出口影响远小于汇率水平,从而导致消极的净出口政策对农产品出口的影响实证结果进行了讨论。

关键词:汇率;农产品出口;中国前言改革开放以来中国在2005年七月人民币汇率形成机制,人民币已波动频繁。

在这方面,密切关注了对人民币汇率的影响波动对中国出口的影响。

由于每个行业都有自己的特点,其汇率变动可能对不同的行业有不同的影响。

因此,克莱因(1990)指出,影响实际汇率波动对出口贸易在商品的水平下必须进一步调查,。

一般来说,农产品有相对于制成品,和为较低的初始投资成本,存在的长期合同等这样的行业性质特殊。

人们普遍承认,影响汇率变动对农产品贸易的不同,对制造品贸易也不同。

经谢尔登和马克克劳斯顿(2002)证实,相对于其他行业,实际汇率不确定性具有较显著的负向影响农产品贸易的作用。

出口瓜果 标准

出口瓜果 标准

出口瓜果标准When it comes to exporting fruits and vegetables, ensuring adherence to international standards is crucial. 出口水果和蔬菜时,确保符合国际标准至关重要。

Meeting these standards not only ensures the health and safety of consumers but also maintains the reputation of the exporting country. 符合这些标准不仅能确保消费者的健康与安全,还能维护出口国的声誉。

Therefore, it is imperative for exporters to be well-versed in the standards set by importing countries. 因此,出口商有必要熟悉进口国设定的标准。

One of the most common standards that exporters need to comply with is the Maximum Residue Limits (MRLs) for pesticides. 最常见的出口标准之一是对农药最大残留限量的要求。

This entails limiting the amount of pesticide residues present on fruits and vegetables to ensure they are safe for consumption. 这意味着限制水果和蔬菜上的农药残留量,以确保它们适合食用。

Exceeding MRLs can lead to rejection of the shipment or even a ban on future exports, causing significant financial losses. 超出最大残留限量可能导致货物被拒绝或者甚至对未来的出口进行禁止,造成巨大的经济损失。

食品安全专业蔬菜论文中英文外文翻译文献

食品安全专业蔬菜论文中英文外文翻译文献

食品安全专业蔬菜论文中英文外文翻译文献1. 王涛, 徐亚男. 我国蔬菜生产与安全的现状与对策[J]. 广东农业科学, 2010, 37(13): 45-47.2. 斯宪芳, 卢仁志. 蔬菜中的重金属和农药残留及其安全问题的调查分析[J]. 中国环境监测, 2007, 23(5): 116-118.3. 范翠华, 阮荣平, 段爱敏,等. 无公害蔬菜生产技术对蔬菜品质及其营养成分的影响[J]. 广东农业科学, 2009, 36(19): 98-100.4. Yeoh S H, Chua T H. Trace metal levels in vegetables from selected farms in Johor Bahru and Kluang[J]. Malaysian Journal of Nutrition, 2002, 8(1): 11-17.5. Mahdi Y, Richardson D G, Abdulla H K, et al. Heavy metal content of some vegetables collected from different areas of Baghdad city, Iraq[J]. Environmental Monitoring and Assessment, 2012, 184(11): 6813-6821.6. 潘云贤, 王振球. 现代环境背景下蔬菜农药安全问题的研究与探讨[J]. 科技资讯, 2007(19): 575.7. 鲍云飞, 顾振中. 蔬菜中农药残留标准及其对我国的启示[J]. 中国农业资源与区划, 2010, 31(2): 23-26.8. 杨忠伦. 我国现代农业生产与蔬菜种植技术的发展现状及对策思考[J]. 产业技术创新, 2018(17): 71.以上8篇文献主要探讨了蔬菜生产与安全问题,包括无公害蔬菜生产技术对蔬菜品质及其营养成分的影响,以及蔬菜中的重金属和农药残留及其安全问题的调查分析等方面。

农业食品安全标准了解国内外农产品食品安全标准的要求

农业食品安全标准了解国内外农产品食品安全标准的要求

农业食品安全标准了解国内外农产品食品安全标准的要求农业食品安全是任何国家都非常重视的问题。

由于食品安全事关公众健康,各国纷纷制定了一系列严格的农产品食品安全标准,以确保食品的质量和安全。

本文将介绍国内外农产品食品安全标准的要求及其对农业发展的影响。

一、国内农产品食品安全标准要求在中国,农产品食品安全标准经过多年的完善和发展,形成了一套相对完整的体系。

国内农产品食品安全标准主要包括农药残留限量、兽药残留限量、重金属限量等要求。

其中,农药残留限量是农产品中农药残留量的最高允许限度,以保障食品不受农药污染。

兽药残留限量是指农产品中兽药残留量的标准,以确保食品不受动物药物残留的影响。

重金属限量则是指农产品中重金属含量的最高允许限度,以防止农产品受到重金属污染。

此外,国内农产品食品安全标准还包括了品质要求、包装标识、生产管理等方面的要求。

品质要求主要是针对食品的外观、味道、营养成分等进行严格的检验,保证食品的质量。

包装标识要求则是要求农产品在包装上必须标明生产日期、保质期、生产厂商等信息,方便消费者了解产品的来源和保质期。

生产管理要求是指在农产品的生产、存储、加工等过程中,必须符合一定的卫生、安全标准,确保食品不受污染。

总的来说,国内农产品食品安全标准的要求非常严格,旨在保障公众的健康和权益。

这些标准的制定和实施,对于提高农产品的质量、确保食品安全起到了至关重要的作用。

二、国外农产品食品安全标准要求国外农产品食品安全标准的要求各有不同,但大致可以归纳为三个方面:食品卫生安全、质量要求和标识规定。

在食品卫生安全方面,国外标准要求农产品在生产、加工、包装和运输过程中要遵循严格的卫生标准,禁止使用有害物质,确保食品不受污染。

此外,对于一些敏感物质和致癌物质的检测也相当严格,以保证食品的安全性。

质量要求方面,国外标准对农产品的外观、色泽、口感、营养成分等均有详细的规定。

只有符合这些要求的产品才能销售到市场上。

标识规定方面,国外标准对农产品的包装和标识要求非常严格。

食品安全专业中英文对照外文翻译文献

食品安全专业中英文对照外文翻译文献

中英文翻译(文档含英文原文和中文翻译)附件1:翻译译文热处理对豆奶(豆腥味)过氧化脂质含量的影响豆腥味是导致豆奶风味不理想的重要因素,为了以最大限度的降低豆奶的豆腥味,我们研究了热处理对过氧化脂质的影响,是影响豆腥味的一个重要因素。

我们还以豆奶为原料并在制作过程中使用加热工序制备了各种甜点,从而通过感官实验来评价加热对其的影响。

经过浸泡和在75℃热处理的肿涨的大豆在相对湿度80-90%处理十分钟的过氧化脂质的含量比大豆中缺乏脂氧合酶和14%或更少的热处理的大豆制备出的豆奶的过氧化脂质含量要大大降低。

此外,设计热烫浸泡和肿胀的大豆在沸水中处理了30秒的豆奶的过氧化脂质含量可以与缺失脂肪氧合酶的大豆制作出的豆奶过氧化脂质含量相媲美。

蛋奶布丁,巴伐利亚奶油以及经过热处理的大豆制作出的豆腐其中的豆腥味都得到了显著的改善。

关键词:大豆豆奶过氧化脂质豆腥味大豆长期以来都是作为高营养食品代名词在日本人的饮食文化中具有具足轻重的作用。

最近的研究表明,大豆蛋白具有降低胆固醇的作用(爱德森等人,1995),大豆皂苷具有抗癌活性(肯尼迪,1995),以及大豆异黄酮对乳腺癌和前列腺癌具有一定的抑制作用(彼得森&贝尔内斯,1991;彼得森G&贝尔内斯S,1993),以及对于骨质疏松症(土田等人,1999)具有一定的预防作用。

根据以上情况可知,由大豆制成的加工食品的价值就是作为人体异黄酮的来源。

大豆被用于很多的食品中,包括豆腐,纳豆,味精,酱油,豆浆。

豆奶作为一种可利用的饮料,可以广泛应用于果冻,蛋奶布丁等甜品的制作原料。

然而,脂肪氧合酶产生的独特的豆腥味对消费者的喜好产生了重大的影响。

因此尽可能的减少豆腥味是能够使豆浆脱颖而出并广泛推广的关键性的挑战。

有几种用于激活脂肪氧合酶的方法已经被提出:温水处理研磨的方法(越后等,1991),其中,大豆在70℃热水中浸泡,然后用95℃的热水进行匀浆;热烫(赛斯&纳特,1988)的方法,用99.3℃的热水进行处理,以及微波加热的方法(王&托莱多,1987)。

21.full 农产品出口外文翻译

21.full     农产品出口外文翻译

Policy Reforms Affecting Agricultural Incentives:Much Achieved,Much StillNeededKym AndersonFor decades,earnings from farming in many developing countries have been depressed by a pro-urban bias in own-country policies,as well as by governments of richer countries favoring their farmers with import barriers and subsidies.Both sets of policies reduce national and global economic welfare and inhibit agricultural trade and economic growth.They almost certainly add to inequality and poverty in developing countries, since three-quarters of the world’s billion poorest people depend on farming for their live-lihood.During the past two decades,however,numerous developing country governments have reduced their sectoral and trade policy distortions,while some high-income countries also have begun reducing market-distorting aspects of their farm policies.The author surveys the changing extent of policy distortions to prices faced by developing-country farmers over the past half century,and provides a summary of new empirical estimates from a global economy-wide model that yield estimates of how much could be gained by removing the interventions remaining as of2004.The author concludes by pointing to the scope and prospects for further pro-poor policy reform in both developing and high-income countries.JEL codes:F13,F14,Q17,Q18For many decades agricultural protection and subsidies in high-income(and some middle-income)countries have been depressing international prices of farm products,which lowers the earnings of farmers and associated rural businesses in developing countries(Johnson1991;Tyers and Anderson1992).Those policies almost certainly add to inequality and poverty,since three-quarters of the world’s poorest people depend directly or indirectly on agriculture for their main income (World Bank2007).Currently less than15million relatively wealthy farmers in developed countries,with an average of almost80hectares per worker,are being The World Bank Research Observer#The Author2009.Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/THE WORLD BANK.All rights reserved.For permissions,please e-mail:journals.permissions@ doi;10.1093/wbro/lkp014Advance Access publication November9,200925:21–55helped at the expense of not only consumers,taxpayers,and producers of other tradables in those rich countries but also the majority of the1.3billion relatively impoverished farmers and their large families in developing countries who,on average,have to earn a living from just2.5hectares per worker.But in addition to this external policy influence on rural poverty,the govern-ments of many developing countries have directly taxed their farmers over the past half-century.A well-known and often-cited example is the taxing of exports of plantation crops in post-colonial Africa(Bates1981).Furthermore,many developing countries in the1960s and1970s chose also to pursue an import-substituting industrialization strategy,predominantly by restricting imports of manufactures.As Krueger,Schiff,and Valde´s(1988,1991)showed in their seminal multi-country study,this indirectly taxed other tradable sectors in those developing economies,including agriculture.Thus the price incentives facing farmers in many developing countries have been depressed by both own-country and other countries’farm,food,and trade policies.I will survey the extent to which government policies at home and abroad have distorted prices faced by developing-country farmers over the past half-century.I begin with a brief examination of the methodology required to measure the extent of own-country distortions to farmer incentives.I then survey analyses of the effects of those agricultural and trade policies on incentives over time,focusing on the worsening of that situation between the1950s and early 1980s and on the progress that has been made over the25years since then.Notwithstanding recent reforms,many price distortions remain in the agricul-tural sector of both developing and high-income countries.I provide a summary of new empirical estimates from a global economy-wide model that indicate how much could be gained by removing the interventions remaining as of2004.I conclude by pointing to the scope and prospects for further pro-poor policy reform in both developing and high-income countries.National Distortions to Incentives:Basic Theory1Bhagwati(1971)and Corden(1997)define the concept of a market policy distor-tion as something that governments impose to create a gap between the marginal social return to a seller and the marginal social cost to a buyer in a transaction. Such a distortion creates an economic cost to society which can be estimated using welfare-measuring techniques such as those pioneered by Harberger (1971).As Harberger notes,this focus allows a great simplification in evaluating the marginal costs of a set of distortions:changes in economic costs can be evalu-ated by taking into account the changes in volumes directly affected by such dis-tortions,ignoring all other changes in prices.In the absence of divergences such 22The W orld Bank Research Observer,vol.25,no.1(February2010)as externalities,the measure of a distortion is the gap between the price paid and the price received,irrespective of whether the level of these prices is affected by the distortion.2Importantly,the total effect of distortions on the agricultural sector will depend not just on the size of the direct agricultural policy measures,but also on the magnitude of distortions generated by direct policy measures altering incentives in non-agricultural sectors.It is relative prices,and hence relative rates of government assistance,that affect producers’incentives.In a two-sector model an import tax has the same effect on the export sector as an export tax: the Lerner(1936)Symmetry Theorem.This carries over to a model that has many sectors,and is unaffected if there is imperfect competition domestically or internationally or if some of those sectors produce only non-tradables (Vousden1990,pp.46–7).The Symmetry Theorem is therefore also relevant for considering distortions within the agricultural sector.In particular,if import-competing farm industries are protected,for example via import tariffs,this has similar effects on incentives to produce exportables as does an explicit tax on agricultural exports;and if both measures are in place,this is a double imposition on farm exporters.Direct Agricultural DistortionsConsider a small,open,perfectly competitive national economy with many firms producing a homogeneous farm product with just primary factors.In the absence of externalities,processing,producer-to-consumer wholesale plus retail marketing margins,exchange rate distortions,and domestic and international trading costs,that country would maximize national economic welfare by allow-ing the domestic producer and consumer prices of that product to both equal E times P,where E is the domestic currency price of foreign exchange and P is the foreign currency price of this identical product in the international market.That is,any government-imposed diversion from those two equalities,in the absence of any market failures or externalities,would be welfare-reducing for that small economy.Price-distorting Trade Measures at the National Border.The most common distortion is an ad valorem tax on competing imports(usually called a tariff),t m.Such a tariff on imports is the equivalent of a production subsidy and a consumption tax, both at rate t m.If that tariff on the imported primary agricultural product is the only distortion,its effect on producer incentives can be measured as the nominal rate of assistance(NRA)to farm output conferred by border price support(NRA BS), which is the unit value of production at the distorted price,less its value at the Anderson23undistorted free market price,expressed as a fraction of the undistorted price:3NRA BS¼EÂPð1þt mÞÀEÂPEÂP¼t mð1ÞThe effect of that import tariff on consumer incentives in this simple economy is to generate a consumer tax equivalent(CTE)on the agricultural product forfinal consumers:CTE¼t mð2ÞThe effects of an import subsidy are identical to those in equations(1)and(2)for an import tax,but t m in that case would have a negative value.Governments sometimes also intervene with an export subsidy s x(or an export tax,in which case s x would be negative).If that were the only intervention,then:NRA BS¼CTE¼s xð3ÞDomestic Producer and Consumer Price-distorting Measures.Some governments provide a direct production subsidy for farmers,s f(or production tax,in which case s f is negative,including via informal taxes in kind by local and provincial governments).In that case,if only this distortion is present,the effect on producer incentives can be measured as the nominal rate of assistance to farm output con-ferred by domestic price support(NRA DS),which is as above except s f replaces t m or s x,but the CTE in that case is zero.Similarly,if the government just imposes a consumption tax c c on this product(or consumption subsidy,in which case c c is negative),the CTE is as above except c c replaces t m or s x,but the NRA DS in that case is zero.The combination of domestic measures and border price support provides the following total rate of assistance to output,NRA o,and total consumer tax equival-ent,CTE:NRA o¼NRA BSþNRA DSð4ÞCTE¼NRA BSþc tð5ÞWhat if the Exchange Rate System Is also Distorting Prices?Should a multi-tier foreign exchange rate regime be in place,then another policy-induced price wedge exists.A simple two-tier exchange rate system creates a gap between the price received by all exporters and the price paid by all importers for foreign cur-rency,changing both the exchange rate received by exporters and that paid by importers from the equilibrium rate E that would prevail without this distortion in the domestic market for foreign currency(Bhagwati1978).This requires24The W orld Bank Research Observer,vol.25,no.1(February2010)controls by the government on current account transfers.In the past it was common for exporters to be required to surrender their foreign currency earnings to the central bank for exchange to local currency at a low official rate,which is equivalent to a tax on exports to the extent that the official rate is below what the exchange rate would be in a market without government intervention.That implicit tax on exporters reduces their incentive to export and hence the supply of foreign currencyflowing into the country.With less foreign currency,demanders are willing to bid up its purchase price,providing a potential rent for the govern-ment which can be realized by auctioning off the limited supply of foreign cur-rency extracted from exporters,or by creating a legal secondary market.Either mechanism will create a gap between the official and parallel rates(Dervis,de Melo and Robinson1981).If the government chooses to allocate the limited foreign currency to different groups of importers at different rates,that is called a multiple exchange rate system.Some lucky importers may even be able to purchase it at the low official rate.The more that is allocated and sold to demanders whose marginal valuation is below the equilibrium rate,the greater the unsatisfied excess demand and hence the stronger the incentive for an illegal or“black”market to form,and for less-unscrupulous exporters to lobby the government to legalize the secondary market for foreign exchange and to allow exporters to retain some fraction of their exchange rate earnings for sale in the secondary market.Such a right given to exporters to retain and sell a portion of foreign exchange receipts would increase their incentives to export,and thereby reduce the shortage of foreign exchange and hence the secondary market exchange rate(Tarr1990;Martin 1993).For present purposes,what matters is that,where a country has distortions in its domestic market for foreign currency,the exchange rate relevant for calculat-ing the NRA o or the CTE for a particular tradable product depends,in the case of a dual exchange rate system,on whether the product is an importable or an exportable one,while in the case of multiple exchange rates it depends on the specific rate applying to that product each year.The precise way in which that can be handled is detailed in Anderson and others(2008).What if Farm Production Involves not just Primary Factors but also Intermediate Inputs?Where intermediate inputs are used in farm production,any taxes or sub-sidies on their production,consumption,or trade would alter farm value added and thereby also affect farmer incentives.Sometimes a government will have directly offsetting measures in place,such as a domestic subsidy for fertilizer use by farmers but also a tariff on fertilizer imports.In other situations there will be farm input subsidies but an export tax on thefinal product.In principle all these items could be brought together to calculate an effective rate of direct assistance Anderson25to farm value added.The nominal rate of direct assistance to farm output,NRA o, is a component of that,as is the sum of the nominal rates of direct assistance to all farm inputs,call it NRA i.Where there are significant distortions to input costs, their ad valorem equivalent can be accounted for by summing each input’s NRA times its input–output coefficient to obtain the combined NRA i,and adding that to the farm industry’s nominal rate of direct assistance to farm output,NRA o,to get the total nominal rate of assistance to farm production,NRA.What about Post-farmgate Costs?If a state trading corporation is charging exces-sively for its marketing services and thereby lowering the farm-gate price of a product,for example as a way of raising government revenue in place of an expli-cit tax,the extent of that excess is treated as if it were an explicit tax.Some farm products,including some that are not internationally traded,are inputs into a processing industry that may also be subject to government inter-ventions.In that case the effect of those interventions on the price received by farmers for the primary product also needs to be taken into account.The Mean and Variance of Agricultural NRAs.When it comes to averaging across countries,each polity is an observation of interest,so a simple average is mean-ingful for the purpose of political economy analysis.But if one wants a sense of how distorted agriculture is in a group of countries,a weighted average is needed. The weighted average NRA for covered primary agriculture can be generated by multiplying each primary industry’s share of production(valued at the farm-gate equivalent undistorted prices)by its corresponding NRA and adding across indus-tries.The overall sectoral rate,NRAag,also could include actual or assumed infor-mation for the non-covered commodities and,where it exists,the aggregate value of non-product-specific assistance to agriculture.A weighted average can be gen-erated also for just the tradables part of agriculture—including those industries producing products such as milk and sugar that require only light processing before they can be traded—by assuming that its share of non-product-specific assistance equals its weight in the total.Call that NRAag t.In addition to the mean,it is important to provide also a measure of the dis-persion or variability of the NRA estimates across the covered products.The cost of government policy distortions to incentives in terms of resource misallocation tends to increase as the degree of substitution in production increases(Lloyd 1974).In the case of agriculture which involves the use of farm land that is sector-specific but transferable among farm activities,the greater the variation of NRAs across industries within the sector,the higher will be the welfare cost of those market interventions.A simple indicator of dispersion is the standard devi-ation around the weighted mean of industry NRAs within the agricultural sector. 26The W orld Bank Research Observer,vol.25,no.1(February2010)Trade Bias in Agricultural Assistance.A trade bias index is also needed to indicate the changing extent to which a country’s policy regime has an anti-trade bias within the agricultural sector.This is important because,as mentioned above,the Lerner(1936)Symmetry Theorem demonstrates that a tariff assisting import-competing farm industries has the same effect on farmers’incentives as if there were a tax on agricultural exports;and,if both measures are in place,this is a double imposition on farm exporters.The higher is the nominal rate of assistance to import-competing agricultural production(NRAag m)relative to that for expor-table farm activities(NRAag x),the more incentive producers in that subsector will have to bid for mobile resources that would otherwise have been employed in export agriculture,other things being equal.Indirect Agricultural Assistance or Taxation via Non-agricultural DistortionsIn addition to direct assistance to,or taxation of,farmers,the Lerner(1936) Symmetry Theorem further demonstrates that their incentives are also affected indirectly by government assistance to non-agricultural production in the national economy.The higher is the nominal rate of assistance to non-agricul-tural tradables production(NRAnonag t),the more incentive producers in other tradable sectors will have to bid up the value of mobile resources that would otherwise have been employed in agriculture,other things being equal.If NRAag t is below NRAnonag t,one might expect there to be fewer resources in agriculture than there would be under free market conditions in the country,notwithstand-ing any positive direct assistance to farmers,and conversely.One way to capture this is to calculate a Relative Rate of Assistance,RRA, defined as:RRA¼1þNRAag t1þNRAnonag tÀ1ð6ÞSince an NRA cannot be less than21if producers are to earn anything,neither can an RRA.This measure is a useful indicator for providing international comparisons over time of the extent to which a country’s policy regime has an anti-or pro-agricultural bias.National Distortions to Farmer Incentives:The Evolutionof PoliciesBefore turning to the contemporary(post-World W ar II)situation,it would be insightful to examine briefly the long history of government intervention inAnderson27international markets for farm products by today’s advanced economies,since similar political economy forces may influence policy choices in later-developing countries.Attention then turns to the price-distorting policies of developing countries since the1950s as they became independent from their colonial masters. The Long History in High-income Countries,BrieflyBritain was thefirst country to have an industrial revolution.Prior to that revolu-tion—from the late1100s to the1660s—Britain used export taxes and licenses to prevent domestic food prices from rising excessively.But during1660–90a series of Acts gradually raised food import duties(making imports prohibitive under most circumstances)and reduced export restrictions on grain.These pro-visions were made even more protective of British farmers by the Corn Laws of 1815.True,the famous repeal of the Corn Laws in the mid-1840s heralded a period of relatively unrestricted food trade for Britain,4but then agricultural pro-tection returned in the1930s and steadily increased over the nextfive decades.Similar tendencies have been observed in many other West European countries, although on the Continent the period of free trade in the19th century was con-siderably shorter,and agricultural protection levels during the past150years have been somewhat higher on average than in Britain.Kindleberger(1975) describes how the19th-century free-trade movements in Europe reflected the national economic,political,and sociological conditions of the time.Agricultural trade reform was less difficult for countries such as Britain with overseas terri-tories that could provide the metropolis with a ready supply of farm products.The fall in the price of grain imports from America in the1870s and1880s provided a challenge for all,however.Denmark coped well by moving more into livestock production to take advantage of cheaper grain.Italians coped by sending many of their relatives to the New World.Farmers in France and Germany successfully sought protection from imports,however,and so began the post-Industrial Revolution growth of agricultural protectionism in densely populated countries. Meanwhile,tariffs on West European imports of manufactures were progressively reduced after the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade(GATT)came into force in the late1940s,thereby adding to the encouragement of agricultural relative to manufacturing production(Lindert1991;Findlay and O’Rourke2007).Japan provides an even more striking example of the tendency to switch from taxing to increasingly assisting agriculture relative to other industries.Its industri-alization began later than in Europe,after the opening up of the economy follow-ing the Meiji Restoration in1868.By1900Japan had switched from being a small net exporter of food to becoming increasingly dependent on imports of rice (its main staple food and responsible for more than half the value of domestic food production).This was followed by calls from farmers and their supporters for 28The W orld Bank Research Observer,vol.25,no.1(February2010)rice import controls.Their calls were matched by equally vigorous calls from manufacturing and commercial groups for unrestricted food trade,since the price of rice at that time was a major determinant of real wages in the non-farm sector. The heated debates were not unlike those that led to the repeal of the Corn Laws in Britain six decades earlier.In Japan,however,the forces of protection tri-umphed,and a tariff was imposed on rice imports from1904.That tariff then gradually rose over time,raising the domestic price of rice to more than 30percent above the import price during World War I.Even when there were food riots because of shortages and high rice prices just after that war,the Japanese government’s response was not to reduce protection but instead to extend it to its colonies and to shift from a national to an imperial policy of rice self-sufficiency.That involved accelerated investments in agricultural development in the colonies of Korea and Taiwan behind an ever-higher external tariff wall that by the latter1930s had driven imperial rice prices to more than60percent above those in international markets(Anderson and Tyers1992).After the Pacific War ended and Japan lost its colonies,its agricultural protection growth resumed and spread from rice to an ever-wider range of farm products.The other high-income countries were settled by Europeans relatively recently and are far less-densely populated.They therefore have had a strong comparative advantage in farm products for most of their history following Caucasian settle-ment,and so have felt less need to protect their farmers than Europe or north-east Asia.Indeed Australia and New Zealand until the late20th century tended—like developing countries—to adopt policies that discriminated against their farmers(Anderson,Lloyd and MacLaren2007).Developing Countries since the1950sIn the Republic of Korea and Taiwan,China in the1950s,as in many newly independent developing countries,initially adopted an import-substituting indus-trialization strategy which harmed agriculture.But in those two economies that policy was replaced in the early1960s with a more neutral trade policy that resulted in very rapid export-oriented industrialization.That development strategy in those densely populated economies imposed competitive pressure on the farm sector which,just as in Japan in earlier decades,prompted farmers to lobby(suc-cessfully,as it happened)for ever-higher levels of protection from import protec-tion(Anderson and Hayami1986,ch.2).Many less-advanced and less-rapidly growing developing countries not only adopted import-substituting industrialization strategies in the late1950s or early 1960s(Little,Scitovsky,and Scott1970;Balassa and Associates1971)but also imposed direct taxes on their exports of farm products.The latter practice was especially rife in Africa(Bates1981).It was common in the1950s and1960s, Anderson29and in some cases even in the1970s and1980s,also to use dual or multiple exchange rates so as to tax indirectly both exporters and importers(Bhagwati 1978;Krueger1978).This added to the anti-trade bias of developing countries’trade policies.That policy history is now well known,and has been documented extensively in previous surveys(for example Krueger1984).Less well-known is the extent to which many emerging economies have belatedly followed the examples of Korea and Taiwan in abandoning import-substitution and opening their economies.Some(for example Chile)started in the 1970s,while others(for example India)did not do so in a sustained way until the 1990s.Some have adopted a very gradual pace of reform,with occasional rever-sals,while others have moved rapidly to open markets.Some have reduced export taxes but simultaneously raised import barriers.And some have adopted the rheto-ric of reform but in practice have done little to free up their economies.To get a clear sense of the overall impact of these reform attempts,there is no substitute for empirical analysis that quantifies over time the types of indicators raised in the theory section above.Building on recent work by the International Food Policy Research Institute(IFPRI)and the OECD(Orden and others2007;OECD2007),a World Bank project recently undertook such analysis,to which we now turn. National Distortions to Farmer Incentives:Empirical Estimatespost-World War IIAfter post-World W ar II reconstruction,Japan continued to raise its agricultural pro-tection,just as had been happening in Western Europe,but to even higher levels. Domestic prices exceeded international market prices for grains and livestock pro-ducts in both Japan and the European Community in the1950s,but by less than40 percent.By the early1980s the difference was more than80percent for Japan but was still around40percent for the EC—and was still close to zero for the agricul-tural-exporting rich countries of Australasia and North America(Anderson and Hayami1986,table2.5).Virtually all of that assistance to Japanese and European farmers in that period was due to restrictions on imports of farm products.Since1986the OECD(2008)has been computing annual producer and consu-mer support estimates by member countries.For the OECD member countries as a whole,producer support rose between1986–88and2005–07in US dollar terms (from$239to$263billion)but has come down when expressed as a share of support-inclusive returns to farmers(from37to26percent).Because of some switching of support instruments,including switching to measures that are based on non-current production or on long-term resource retirement,the share of that assistance provided via market price support measures has fallen from three-quar-ters to one-half.When the PSE payment is expressed as a percentage of undistorted30The W orld Bank Research Observer,vol.25,no.1(February2010)prices to make it an NRA,the NRA fall is from59to35percent between1986–88and2005–07(OECD2008).This indicator suggests high-income country pol-icies have become considerably less trade–distorting,at least in proportional terms,even though farmer support in high-income countries has continued to grow in dollar terms because of growth in the value of their farm output.As for developing countries outside north-east Asia,the main comprehensive set of pertinent estimates over time is for the period just prior to when reforms became widespread.They were generated as part of a major study of18developing countries from the1960s to the mid-1980s by Krueger,Schiff,and Valde´s(1988, 1991).That study by the World Bank,whose estimates are summarized in Schiff and Valde´s(1992),shows that the depression of incentives facing farmers has been due only partly to various forms of agricultural price and trade policies, including subsidies to food imports.Much more important in many cases have been those developing countries’non-agricultural policies that hurt their farmers indirectly.The two key ones have been manufacturing protectionism(which attracts resources from agriculture to the industrial sector)and overvalued exchange rates(which attract resources to sectors producing non-tradables,such as services).That indirect impact was negative for all four groups of countries shown in table1,whereas the impact of direct agricultural policies was negative only for the two lowest-income country groups.In addition to the total assistance being more negative the poorer the country group,table1also reveals that it is lower for producers of exportables than for the subsector focused on import-com-peting farm products,suggesting a strong anti-trade bias for the sector as a whole.Since there were no comprehensive multiregion studies of the Krueger,Schiff, and Valde´s type for developing countries that monitored progress over the sub-sequent reform period,5a new study was recently launched by the World Bank aimed atfilling this lacuna.The new study covers not only41developing countries but also14European transition economies as well as20high-income countries.The results from that study6do indeed reveal that there has been a substantial reduction in distortions to agricultural incentives in developing countries over the past two to three decades.They also reveal that progress has not been uniform across countries and regions,and that—contrary to some earlier claims(for example from Jensen,Robinson,and Tarp2002)—the reform process is far from complete.In particular,many countries still have a wide dis-persion in NRAs for different farm industries and in particular have a strong anti-trade bias in the structure of assistance within their agricultural sector;and some countries have“overshot”in the sense that they have moved from having an average rate of assistance to farmers that was negative to one that is positive, rather than stopping at the welfare-maximizing rate of zero.Moreover,the var-iance in rates of assistance across commodities within each country,and in aggre-gate rates across countries,remains substantial;and the beggar-thy-neighbor。

绿色贸易壁垒对我国农产品出口的影响外文翻译文献

绿色贸易壁垒对我国农产品出口的影响外文翻译文献

绿色贸易壁垒对我国农产品出口的影响外文翻译文献(文档含英文原文和中文翻译)Analysis and countermeasure of international green trade barrier The green trade barrier limits the development of the international trade by manysteps. It obstacles the integration of the international economy the free developmentof the world trade. It is in some countries,especially in some developing countriesthe production for export lost greatly. However, under the limitation of the green tradebarrier,the air and water resource have been polluted badly,and the soil resourcedecreasing and the loss of life.1.The definition of the green trade barrier . The green trade barrier is also named as green barrier. It refers to protection of theinner market by means of the limitation by the strict environment protectiontechnology or the green signs inthe import,which can keep the foreign merchandisesoutside. This causes an immense impact on the international trade order. 2.The reason of appearance of green trade barrier 1The change of view of value. Along with the development of the industrialization and the growth of the worldeconomy,the increasing destroy and pollute getting more and more serious. This hasdirectly affected the living and development of human beings. And this successfullydrew an attention of the international society. The way of people thinking, behavior ofconsumption and view of consumption have changed. The new conception of value thethat concentrate on quality of living and creating green civilization; need for greenproduction with pollution and harm to human are increasing. The people in developedcounties have formed a good view of value for green production also providesdeveloping countries chance and challenges. 2The traditional lawless tax barrier gets condemn of the international society. In order to bring up the newborn industries,some mature industries gainunpredicted profit. But even this,they never thought of the protection of the innermarket.However after the operation of the General Agreement On Tariffs andtrade the import tax has been decreased ever since. Non-tax barrier has beenlimitations. The chance and space for traditional trade barrier are getting smaller andsmaller. On this occasion,the developed countries begin to search for new ways oftrade protections for the sake of development of their own industries. And green tradebarrier come into use. 3Different standards in different countries. Economys state stays in different level owing to the different technology level.So there are great differences in the ability of environment protection in differentcountries. This leads to different environment protection standard. It is a hard to saywhich standard is the best one,because different environment standard has a directimpact on the cost. And this would have great impact on the world competence, whichaffected the balance of the international income and expenses .In order to limit theimport from developing countries,the developed countries find the green trade to beexcuses to protect their own industries. 3.The impact of the green tradebarrier on China The green trade barrier has both good and bad impact on one country. But it indeedhas different impact on different countries. Limited by the technology,China has alower ability to deal with the barrier and catch up the chance to improveitself.Moreover,China mostly focuses on export labor-centered production. By far it hasreceived negative impact from the barrier. For the time being,this kind of barrierexists everywhere,and grow stronger and stronger,which has struck our market andeconomy seriously. 1The negative impact on the green trade barrier ①It prevents the export form China and weakens the export internationalcompetence. ②It influences the bilateral even multilateral relationship with other countriesgetting to problems. Recently,the developed countries circumscribe the importation from acclaimingthat those goods are not the green production. Thus bring up the conflictions. Thedeveloped countries enjoy a free form of trade in a certain trade zone,which reducethe standard of trading rather than trading from outside of the zone. So,countries likeChina are hard to break through thetrade barrier. All those confliction are bad forChina. The situations are against China. ③It accelerates the pollution for products and makes the metastasis to China. Thestandard of environment protection are low,the systems are not perfect with lowstandard of green production in China. Because of this,a lot of production of lowquality are entering Chinese market leads to many foreign waste cases spring upeverywhere. All of this shows that China are lacking of a perfect supervising system.Without a good management there will be no efficient working. According to theinvestigation,from 1997 to 2000,the foreign waste are increased from 990,000 tonto 17,500,000 ton. There is evidently no doubt that these foreign waste have madethe environment more serious in China. But in the items got the investment nearlyhave no supervising on environment protection,which let the industries causingpollution have transferred in China. 2The positive impact on the green trade barrier. In the developed countries,the environment policy helps to strengthen themanagement of industry environment,and applies the high tech to develop the greenproduction,which can lower the cost. Thus we can gain high social and economyefficiency,and finally get the production of high quality. ①It does good to Chinas continuous development. The task of environment protection should be accomplished by all the humanbeings.The skills of management in developed countries are in an advantage placethan that in the developing countries. China as a developing country is supposed tolearn the experience of developed countries which can be made good use of topromote the harmonious development of environment and economy development. Weshould insist in the principle of continuous development which is good to ourconstruction of exportation. Furthermore,this can promote the industries to producemore and more technology-focused production and helps to break through the greentrade barrier while doing international trade. ②It get the industries change their trading concept. The law of environment protection in developed countries is more perfect than inChina. The conception of environment protection has been applied in every aspectwhile doing business activity. For example:use green package,sail greenproductionwith green after sail services provided,introduce environment protection knowledge,do promoting of green production with green theme and establish a green image ofcompany. With activities of above,everyone can protect the environment and natureconsciously. 4. Breaking the barrier 1The government plays the role of the lead to help to develop the” greenenvironment protection” industries. ①adjust the construction to the” green environment production industriesquot. ②complete the” law of the green tradequot,resist the barrier. 2For the industries,they should face to the challenge to produce more” greenproductionquot. ①Collecting quotgreen informationquot,developing quotgreen productionquot. The companies are supposed to take part in international economic technologyconference and business trade expo or visit others who are of abundant”greeninformation” and exchange with each other. The most essential way of breaking”green trade barrier”is to establish a nice international image. The industries shouldestablish a good supervision of production design and material picking,productionandwaste recycling,recto explore a green production needed by the market.Furthermore,the industries should pay much attention to financial input and thetraining of the employers. ②Strengthen the green management. Improve the market competence. Thequotgreen management” refers to a management that require industries form akind of sailing conception of conform the rule of green trade by continuous mind andgreen environment requirement. It is an effective way of breaking through thebarrier. The green environment protectionism is recognized as a worldwide trade newproblem,which need to face it and challenge it. Correcting trade standard is allcountries are aware of its unavoidable ability. In the WTO system,environmentprotection has been on the agenda. If we want to be successful in changing China agreat trading country into a great trading world power , we have to doself-improvement and raise the conception of environment protection. So only whenwe make every effort to do improvement can we break through the green tradebarrier. 5. Our strategy and thinking on green trade barriers 1Strengthen education and drumbeating,raise awareness of environmentalprotection. the acceleration of the awareness of environment from all people can notbe separated from extensive publicity and education. Propagandize foreign trade andeconomy and environmental protection,especially do some work on universalenvironmental pact and environmental standards,making all the economic and tradeworkers at different levels fully understand the crucial and practical significance ofenvironment in this field. We should do a good job on the negative reports on foreigntrade and environmental protection,lead environmental protection awareness intoenterprises business decisions,and foster a sense of crisis and urgency. 2Establish and improve environmental protection laws and regulations ,strengthen execution of trade environment. we In the respect of preventing pollution, have set up some laws and regulations,but they are not in accordance with practical needs,maneuverability is not good,punishment is not enough;we are actually using economic methods to makeenterprises buy and sell drainage right,rather than urging them to deal with.Consequently aftertimewe should improve every environmental protection regulationwith the priority of prevention and strengthen supervision and management. Tostrengthen governments environmental management function,to punish acts againstenvironmental laws legally,develop the effect of green products and environmentalsigns,strengthen all the consumers surviving effects,develop green industry intosupporting industry,green product into fist product. 3Develop green market,green product,green marketing. With the strengthening of the awareness of environmental and resource protection anew industry with the purpose of protecting environment and resource——greenindustry is growing fast. At the same time,it has driven the development andformation of green product and green market. It is reported that in the following tenyears green product will lead the main markets in the world. We should adoptourselves with this tide change product designation package promote productquality, increase environmental items, make the best to achieve the standards of everytechnique, security, and sanitation, environment, adopt the tide of greenconsumption andneeds, also developlow-environment-protection-cost, good-quality green productthat is in accordance with universal environmental standards. 4Strengthen international exchange and cooperation,use international power toresist trade barrier. Although Uruguay will make an” Decision on Trade and Environment” toenhance awareness of environmental protection also it will make some basic items inwhich include security items to prevent developing countries from beingdiscriminated by developed countries. Therefore we can make use of some relevantitems and international agreements and unite other developing countries to resistdiscriminating strategies adopted by developed countries who are making use of greenprotection,and promote the development of our foreign trade. 6. Conclusion With the world economy developing fast,the developed country hold higherstandards and stronger awareness of environmental protection. We are in the thedeveloping stage, protection of green products have great effect on the exportationof our products,we must adapt our country and our foreigntriage with this new tideand follow relevant regulations strictly.国际绿色贸易壁垒的分析和采取的对策绿色贸易壁垒通过多种途径限制国际贸易的发展。

我国农产品检测对出口贸易的影响

我国农产品检测对出口贸易的影响

我国农产品检测对出口贸易的影响来源:环球市场信息导报1.绪论随着世界经济和社会持续高速地发展,人民生活水平逐步提高,人们对农产品质量安全也提出更高的要求,农产品质量安全问题越来越引起全社会的关注。

我国是世界上最大的农产品生产国,但是我国农产品占世界农产品贸易的比重却很少,在加入世贸组织之初仅为2.5%[1]。

因此发展我国的农产品贸易是我们加入WTO 后的重要课题之一。

我国检测技术落后,与国外先进的检测技术存在一定差距。

因此,大力开展和完善农产品检测是一项重大而艰巨的任务,也是提高我国农产品国际竞争力的必然的选择。

2.我国农产品检测在外贸中的必要性由于我国农业劳动力成本低,因此在猪肉、禽肉、水产和蔬菜、水果和花卉等产品的出口上具有优势,农产品出口也一直是我国出口创汇的重要来源之一。

然而,我国加入WTO后农产品出口屡屡受阻,而且面临困难越来越多。

我国出口农产品被退回的原因主要有以下三个方面:国内有的产品生产条件和卫生条件不合格。

进口国以提高它的技术要求标准达到一些技术壁垒。

国内目前从质量检验检疫标准与进口国和国际上的认证有差别。

我国的检测技术不够先进,有些农药残留在国内检测符合检出标准或和不得检出,而在国外却被检测出更精确的农药残留量。

减少农产品出口退货是提高我国检测水平的要求;同时,我国应通过多种渠道及时了解美、日、韩等主要贸易国的进口政策和检疫标准,以此为鉴,早日制定出我国自己的与国际接轨的新标准。

20多年前,发达国家就开始实施农药残留监控计划,在国际贸易中也往往以食品安全的正当名义设置种种技术壁垒,对进口食品中农药、兽药残留量提出了愈来愈严格的要求。

3.我国农产品检测存在的问题农产品存在自身的弱质性,检测标准有待于提高。

相比与发达国家,我国经济技术落后,在改良品种和培育新品种方面缺乏能力,因此,农业自身的弱质性决定了出口农产品主要集中在附加值低的劳动密集型和资本密集型的品种上。

这样的农产品质量低,技术含量不高,很容易成为进口国拒绝进口的理由。

应对果品出口食品安全与卫生标准的挑战

应对果品出口食品安全与卫生标准的挑战

应对果品出口食品安全与卫生标准的挑战目录一、引言 (2)二、加强果园管理与病虫害防治 (2)三、完善果品采摘、加工与包装流程 (5)四、建立严格的检验检测体系 (7)五、加强员工培训与食品安全意识 (10)六、积极应对国际食品安全事件 (13)一、引言声明:本文内容来源于公开渠道或根据行业大模型生成,对文中内容的准确性不作任何保证。

本文内容仅供参考,不构成相关领域的建议和依据。

与传统的水果相比,绿色果品和有机果品在养分含量方面更加丰富,味道更加鲜美。

这是因为它们没有被农药、化肥等污染物污染,土壤也没有被长期耕种所破坏,水果的自然成分得以充分保留,味道更加浓郁。

绿色果品和有机果品的种植方式有助于维护生态系统的平衡,减少温室气体的排放,促进农业可持续发展。

绿色果品与有机果品的兴起为果品出口市场带来了新的机遇和挑战。

为了抓住机遇、应对挑战,出口企业应积极提升产品质量和附加值,加强品牌建设和市场推广,同时密切关注国际贸易动态和政策变化,灵活调整出口策略和市场布局。

随着消费者对绿色果品和有机果品的认可度不断提高,市场需求持续增长。

特别是在发达国家市场,绿色果品和有机果品已成为高端市场的代表,市场前景广阔。

二、加强果园管理与病虫害防治(一)果园管理体系的完善1、标准化果园建设在果品出口市场中,果园作为生产源头,其管理水平直接影响到果品的质量与安全。

因此,完善果园管理体系,推进标准化果园建设是关键。

这包括果园选址的合理性,确保土壤、水源及气候条件适宜果树生长;果园基础设施的完善,如灌溉系统、排水系统、防护林等,以提高果园的抗灾能力;以及果园布局的科学性,合理安排树种、株行距等,优化果树生长环境。

2、精细化管理实施精细化管理,通过定期监测土壤养分、水分含量及果树生长状况,及时调整管理措施。

利用现代信息技术,如物联网、大数据等,实现果园环境的智能化监控,提高管理效率和精准度。

同时,建立果园管理档案,记录果树生长周期中的各项管理措施,为果品质量追溯提供依据。

发达国家食品安全标准对中国食品出口的影响

发达国家食品安全标准对中国食品出口的影响

Effects of Food Safety Standards in Developed Countries on the Food Export of China 作者: 于丽艳[1];王殿华[1]
作者机构: [1]天津科技大学经济与管理学院,天津300222
出版物刊名: 华东经济管理
页码: 66-69页
年卷期: 2011年 第10期
主题词: 食品安全标准;技术性贸易壁垒;食品出口
摘要:文章对发达国家食品安全标准成为我国食品出口的技术性贸易壁垒的原因进行分析;利用调研数据结合中国食品出口情况,分析了发达国家食品安全标准对中国食品出口的影响。

由于对食品行业的保护一直是发达国家贸易保护的重点,同时保护健康意识的增强使消费者对食品安全指标的要求越来越高,而中国食品安全标准不规范,食品安全评估工作起步较晚,从而造成中国出口的食品受有关食品安全标准影响较大;提出了及时掌握国外新的法律法规,推行标准化认证工作,转变生产模式及转变观念等中国食品出口突破国外技术壁垒的对策。

中国农食产品标准国际化能否提升出口产品质量?

中国农食产品标准国际化能否提升出口产品质量?

How Does the Internationalization of China’s Agri-food Product Standards Affect the Product Quality of Agri-food Firms’ Exports?
作者: 王学君[1];苏冬梅[1]
作者机构: [1]南京农业大学经济管理学院
出版物刊名: 产经评论
页码: 112-125页
年卷期: 2020年 第2期
主题词: 出口产品质量;农食产品标准;国际标准;国家标准;遵从成本
摘要:执行国际标准能够促进产品质量提升,但也会给企业带来过高的遵从成本,从而可能不
利于企业产品质量的提升。

选取2000-2013年中国农食产品标准数据与企业-产品层面海关数据,实证分析中国农食产品标准"国际化"对企业出口产品质量的影响。

结果显示:从整体来看,标准"国际化"对企业出口产品质量效应显著为负,而我国自行制定的国家标准对质量影响显著为正;
按照对国际标准采纳程度分类,以及对出口产品和出口目的国发展程度分类,分样本检验发现,标准"国际化"对企业出口产品质量存在异质性影响。

为此,照搬发达国家主导制订的国际标准不适
用于中国出口企业,可能会由于过高的遵从成本阻碍企业产品质量升级。

另一方面,以中国为代表
的发展中国家需积极参与到国际标准的制定中,从而减少过高遵从成本对产品质量升级及出口带
来的不利影响。

食品安全标准对中国禽肉出口的影响及政策模拟

食品安全标准对中国禽肉出口的影响及政策模拟

食品安全标准对中国禽肉出口的影响及政策模拟郭俊芳;武拉平【期刊名称】《科技与经济》【年(卷),期】2015(028)001【摘要】基于1996-2012年中国与11个主要禽肉进口国和地区间的面板数据,通过建立引力模型,采取因变量删失的处理技术,对土霉素最大残留限量水平在我国禽肉出口中的影响进行定量分析,结果表明,进口国和地区土霉素最大残留限量标准每严格1% ppb,中国禽肉出口将减少2.51%.在此基础上进一步拓展,利用估计的弹性系数,以CODEX作为基线标准模拟研究了国家间标准的统一对中国禽肉出口的影响.分析表明,如果各国均按照国际食品法典委员会制定的CODEX标准执行,对中国的禽肉出口将是有利的,2012年中国禽肉出口将增加13.04亿元.另外,各国间标准的互认和协调也有利于推进贸易自由化.短期内中国应尽可能选择和开拓贸易壁垒较低的市场,长期来看,要加强和完善国内农产品生产加工和检验检疫标准体系的建设,努力推进各国食品安全标准的统一和互认.【总页数】5页(P47-51)【作者】郭俊芳;武拉平【作者单位】中国农业大学经济与管理学院,北京100083;中北大学经济管理学院,太原030051;中国农业大学经济与管理学院,北京100083【正文语种】中文【相关文献】1.食品安全标准对中国农产品出口的影响——以苹果出口为例 [J], 张肇中;张红凤2.发达国家食品安全标准对中国食品出口的影响 [J], 于丽艳;王殿华3.国外食品安全标准对中国农产品出口影响的评估 [J], 陈来春;杨军;克里斯多夫·芬德利;李鹏;刘艳辉;李文4.中美贸易视角下食品安全标准对中国农业食品出口的影响 [J], 杨晓云;黄福高5.一带一路沿线国家金融监管对我国肉食出口供给侧结构改革的影响—书评《非关税措施对中国禽肉出口的影响研究》 [J], 黄昊因版权原因,仅展示原文概要,查看原文内容请购买。

  1. 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
  2. 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
  3. 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。

外文翻译原文Measuring the Effect of Food Safety Standards on China’sAgricultural ExportsMaterial Source: Review of World Economics Author:ChunlaiChen,JunYang, andChristopher Findlay1 IntroductionSince 2002, China’s agricultural trade has increas ed rapidly, reaching US$50.44 billion in 2005, and as expectedChina has dramatically increased imports of land-intensive agricultural products, particularly cereals (mainly wheat), vegetable oils and vegetable oilseeds (mainly palm oil and soybeans), and raw materials for textiles (mainly cotton and wool).China has also increased exports of labour-intensive agricultural products, particularly processed agricultural products, but at a slower pace. From 2002 to 2005, the annual growth rate of agricultural imports was 31.53 per cent while that of agricultural exports was 11.65 per cent. As a result, in 2004 and 2005 agricultural imports exceeded agricultural exports and China reported its first two consecutive years of a deficit in agricultural trade since the 1990s(Chen 2006).From 1992 to 2005, China’s comparative advantage revealed by the net export ratio (NER) in agriculture changed gradually. As shown in Figure 1,China’s revealed comparative advantage in the whole agricultural sector declined, especially after 2002, and since 2004 China’s agricultural sector as a whole has lost comparative advantage in international trade. Also since the 1990s, and especially since the early 2000s, China’s comparative advantage revealed by NER in labour-intensive agricultural products has been declining dramatically (Chen 2006).Figure 1: China’s Revealed Comparative Advantage Indices (NER) of Whole Agricultural Sector and Products by Factor Intensity of ProductionSource: Chen (2006).Undoubtedly, the changes in revealed comparative advantage in agriculture have mainly been the result of China’s fas t economic growth, dramatic structural changes and continued increase in per capita income. However, other factors could also affect China’s revealed comparative advantage in agriculture. The revealed comparative advantage indices are not only created by underlying economic forces but are often significantly affected by government policies with respect to international trade. This problem has been more serious for trade in agricultural products. In particular, the developed countries have resorted to sanitary and phytosanitary (SPS) measures for animal and plant health and technical barriers to trade (TBT) to block and restrict agricultural imports, especially from developing countries where food safety and technical standards are often low as compared to tho se of developed countries. This has seriously affected the developing countries’ exports of agricultural products in which they have a comparative advantage.In the case of China, Chinese farmers and exporters had anticipated a large, positive impact on domestic production and the export of agricultural products with accession to the World Trade Association (WTO),especially for labour-intensive agricultural products such as vegetables , fruits, animal products, and fish and aquatic products. In fact, these products have been hardest hit by the application of SPS standards. Our question is whether this has limited the growth in these agricultural exports by China.Therefore, this paper examines and measures the impact of food safety standards on China’s agricu ltural exports. Section 2 presents some empiricalevidence of SPS and TBT measures affecting China’s agricultural exports in recent years. Section 3 discusses the methodology of the study. Section 4 presents the specification of variables and data sources.Section 5 conducts an econometric analysis of the impact of SPS and TBT standards on China’s agricultural exports for selected agricultural products. Section 6 discusses the effect of food safety standards on China’s agricultural exports and compares the effect of food safety standards and import tariffs on China’s agricultural exports. Section 7 concludes the paper and discusses some policy implications.2 Empirical Evidence of the Impact of SPS and TBT Measures on China’s Agricultural ExportsAccording to Chinese government official sources, SPS and TBT measures have resulted in huge direct losses for China’s agricultural exports. In 2001, about US$7 billion worth of Chinese exports were affected by SPS and TBT measures. In early 2002, the EU began to ban imports of Chinese animal-derived food, and seafood and aquatic products, resulting in a 70 per cent slump in China’s aquatic product exports during the second half of that year (MOFCOM 2005). Also, China’s Ministry of Commerce (MOFCOM) found that about 90 per cent of China’s exporters of foodstuffs, domestic produce, and animal by-products were affected by foreign technical trade barriers and suffered losses totalling US$9 billion in 2002 (China Daily 2003).China’s recent experience with SPS barriers hav e been mainly with the EU, Japan and the United States. These three economies accounted for 41, 30 and 24 per cent respectively of China’s trade losses attributed to SPS measures in 2002 (Zhu 2003). In other examples, (Dong and Jensen 2004), in November 2001, 300 metric tons (mt) of shrimp shipped from Zhoushan in the Zhejiang province to the EU were discovered to contain 0.2 parts per billion of Chloramphenicol. As a result, the EU suspended imports of Chinese products of animal origin intended for human consumption or for use in animal feeds. Affected products included rabbit meat, poultry meat,and crustaceans such as shrimp and prawns. Later, other countries, including Hungary, Russia and Japan, implemented stricter inspections of poultry meat from China. As a consequence, exports of poultry meat from China declined by about 33 per cent in 2002 compared with the previous year.In 2002 Japan tightened the Maximum Residual Limit (MRL) of the pesticide Chlorpyrifos in spinach from0.1 ppm to 0.01 ppm. As a result, in July 2002 Japanblocked imports of frozen spinach from China after finding pesticides. Prior to this ban, import from China were around US$30 million to US$35 million, accounted for 99 per cent of Japan’s annual imports of 40,000 to 50,000 mt of spinach. Japan’s restriction on Chinese exports of frozen spinach lasted until February 2003. In May 2003, after detecting higher-than-permitted pesticide residue, Japan again advised importers not to import Chinese frozen spinach, and this import ban was not lifted until June 2004. China’s export of spinach to Japan dropped dramatically, from the highest level of US$33.89 million in 2001, to US$14.3 million in 2002 and US$3.95 million in 2003. In 2004 and 2005, China’s export of spinach to Japan recovered slightly, but it was still lower than the 1994 export level.Japan, which is China’s largest agricultural product export market, has introduced the Positive List System for Agricultural Chemical Residues in Foods (Ministry of Health, Labour and Welfare of Japan 2006), which took effect on 29May 2006. Agricultural chemicals include pesticides, feed additives and veterinary drugs in a total of 797 categories. The system sets 53862 MRL standards.A uniform limit will be applied to agricultural chemicals for which MRLs are not established. The uniform limit is 0.01 ppm, which means for 100mt of agricultural products, the agricultural chemical residuals cannot exceed 1 gram.From August 2002 to July 2003, the United States Food and Drug Administration (U.S. FDA) refused entry to 1,285 shipments of Chinese foodstuffs. Agricultural and aquatic products accounted for 630 of these shipments, or nearly half of all refusals (Dong and Jensen 2004). Most recently, from June 2005 to May 2006, the U.S. FDA refused 1,925 Chinese shipments from entry into the United States, of which 945 shipments were agricultural products, accounting for 49 per cent of the total refusals (U.S. FDA 2006).Most refusals result from violations of SPS measures. Excessive pesticide residues, low food hygiene, unsafe additives, contamination, and misuse of veterinary drugs have been major issues.3 Methodology and Econometric ModelWe aim to measure the effect of food safety standards on China’s exports of two groups of agricultural commodities—vegeta bles, and fish and aquatic products. These two categories of agricultural products were selected because not only are they very important in China’s agricultural exports, but also they are the main targets of SPS regulations.We apply a gravity model in which the interaction between two areas is afunction of the concentration of relevant variables in the two areas, and of the distance between them. Tinbergen (1962) pioneered its use in a study of the levels of bilateral trade flows. Linnemann (1966) elabora ted the Tinbergen model and his results implicitly suggested that the relative distance is important in the determination of trade levels. Leamer (1974) used the framework laid out in his earlier work with Stern to test the adequacy of traditional trade theory, alongside more recent theory which stresses the importance of scale economies. Some economists have also used the gravity model in studies of regional trade blocs, regional trade bias and home country trade bias.The theoretical validity of the gravity model has been examined by Niedercorn and Bechdolt (1969) within the framework of utility theory. Deardorff (1995) demonstrated that the model is compatible with neo-classical models. The gravity model has also been derived in an imperfect competition/differentiated product framework. Anderson and van Win-coop (2003) argued that estimated gravity equations do not have a theoretical foundation and that their estimation suffers from omitted variables bias. They derived the theoretical gravity equation based on the CES utility function. The key implication of the theoretical gravity equation is that trade between regions depends on the bilateral barrier between them relative to average trade barriers that both regions face with all their trading partners (multilateral resistance).The gravity model has also been used to estimate the impact of product standards and food safety standards on trade flows.Moenius (2000) used the gravity model to provide a framework for estimating the effect of product standards on trade flows. Otsuki et al. (2001) used it to estimate the impact of the EU’s new aflatoxin standards on food imports from Africa. The study suggests that the implementation of the new standard will have a negative impact on African exports of cereals, dried fruits and nuts to Europe.Wilson et al. (2003) used the gravity model to examine the impact of drug residue standards on trade in beef and found that Tetracycline standard in beef has a negative and significant impact on world trade in beef. The study pred icts that if international standards set by CODEX were followed in antibiotics, global trade in beef would rise by over US$3.2 billion.Using the gravity model to examine Japan’s stricter pesticide residue limit on vegetables exports from China, Sun et al. (2005) found that Japan’s stricter Chlorpyrifos standard has a negative impact on China’s vegetables export to Japan.The model used in this study can be written as:where EX k ij is the export value of commodity k from exporting country i toimporting country j, X i are exporting country variables, X j are importing country variables and R are resistance variables.In this study, the exporting country is China and the exporting country variable, Xi, is the output of China in commodity k. The importing country variable, X j ,is the GDP of importing country j.The resistance variables include three factors: distance (DIST) between China and importing country j, MRL standards of pesticide or veterinary in commodity k imposed by importing country j and the import tariff rate (TRF) on commodity k imposed by importing country j.Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) show that bilateral trade depends on both origin and destination price levels, which are themselves related to the existence of trade barriers (multilateral resistance). In our gravity equation, we ignored the relative prices and therefore the multilateral resistance variables and so our gravity equation could lead to biased estimates. We solve this problem by using importer-specific fixed-effects.Therefore the model estimated in this study is:翻译测量中国的农产品出口的食品安全标准的影响资料来源:世界经济回顾作者:陈春来、杨军、Christopher Findlay1、说明自2002年以来,中国的农产品贸易迅速增加,2005年达到504.4亿美元,同时按照预期中国极大地增加土地密集型农产品的进口,尤其是谷物(主要是小麦),蔬菜油和蔬菜油籽进口(主要是棕榈油和大豆),和纺织品原材料(主要是棉花和羊毛)。

相关文档
最新文档