股权结构与公司业绩[外文翻译]
新兴市场领域,股权结构与公司价值的关系【外文翻译】
外文翻译原文Ownership and Firm Value in Emerging MarketsMaterial Source:/finkvl/LinsJFQA2003.pdf Author: Karl V. LinsAbstractThis paper investigates whether management stock ownerahip and large non-managemcot blockholder share owneiship are related to firm value across a sample of 1433 firms from 18 emerging maikets. When a management group's control l i g ^ exceed its cash flaw tights, I find that finn values are lower. I also find that large non-management control limits blockholdings are positively related to firm value. Both of these e£fects are significantly more pronounced in countries with low shareholder protection. One interpretation of these results is that extemal shareholder protection mechanisms play a role in restraining managerial agency costs and that laige non-management blockholders can act as a paitial substitute for missing institutional governance mechanistns.I. IntroductionRecent research shows that large blockholders dominate the ownership structures of firms not domiciled in the U.S. or a few other developed countries (Shleifernd and Vishny (1997), La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishny (LLSV)(1998), La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, and Shleifer (1999), Claessens, Djankov, and Lang (2000), and Denis and McConnell (2003)). This research suggests that such concentrated ownership coincides with a lack of investor protection because owners who are not protected from controllers will seek to protect themselves by becoming controllers. When control has incremental value beyond any cash flow rights associated with equity ownership, shareholders will seek to obtain control rights that exceed cash flow rights in a given firm. Around the world, control in excess of proportional ownership is usually achieved through pyramid structures in which one firm is controlled by another firm, which may itself be controlled by some other entity.The management group (and its family members) is usually the largestblockholder of a firm at the top of the pyramid and there is significant overlap between the top firm's management group and the managers of each firm down the line in the pyramid. Thus, the controlling managers at the top of a pyramid are generally able to exercise effective control of all the firms in the pyramid, while they bear relatively less of the cash flow consequences of exercising their control in each firm down the line. Finally, irrespective of pyramiding, managers of a given firm sometimes issue and own shares with superior voting rights to achieve control rights that exceed their cash flow rights in the firm (Zingales (1994), Nenova(2003)). Taken together, the net result is that a great number of firms around the world have managers who possess control rights that exceed their cash flow rights in the firm, which, fundamentally, gives rise to potentially extreme managerial agency problems.The extent to which managerial agency problems affect firm value is likely to depend on several factors. If there are cash flow incentives that align managers' interests with those of outside shareholders, this should raise firm values. Alternatively, if a management group is insulated firom outside shareholder demands,a situation often referred to as managerial entrenchment, managers choose to use their control to extract corporate resources; this consumption (or expected consumption) of the private benefits of control should reduce firm values. When managers have control in excess of their proportional ownership, the consumption of private control benefits is especially likely since this type of ownership structure both reduces cash flow incentive alignment and increases the potential for managerial entrenchment Conversely, if managers act in the best interest of all shareholders, then firm values should not depend on managrial control rights.Finally, to the extent that management's control rights are correlated with its cash flow rights, additional managerial control could result in higher firm values.Non-management blockholders might also impact firm value. If there are large non-management shareholders that have both the incentive to monitor managementand enough control to infiuence management such that cash flow is increased,firm values should be higher because all equity holders share in this benefit of control. Of course, as with managers, large non-management blockholders might choose to use their power to extract corporate resources, which would reduce firm values. Finally, all of these factors are potentially even more important where extemal shareholder protection is the weakest.This paper tests the above hypotheses using a sample of 1433 firms from 18 emerging markets.Emerging markets provide an excellent laboratory to study the valuation effectsof ownership structure for several reasons. First pyramid ownership structures are prevalent across virtually all emerging markets. Second, emerging markets generally suffer from a lack of shareholder and creditor protection and have poorly developed legal systems (LLSV (1998)). Finally, markets for corporate control (i.e., the takeover market) are generally underdeveloped in emerging markets(The Economist Intelligence Unit (1998)). Overall, where extemal corporate governance is weak and managerial control often exceeds its proportional ownership, extreme managerial agency problems may arise because the private benefits of control are large. Non-management blockholders may be especially beneficial to minority shareholders if they help fill the extemal governance void.LLSV (2002) and Claessens, Djankov, Fan, and Lang (2002) provide some evidence on the relation between firm value, as measured by Tbbin's Q, and ownership structure across different economies. Both papers focus exclusively on the ownership characteristics of a firm's largest shareholder, which is usually, but not always, the management group and its family. These papers do not explicitly test how the relation between management/family ownership and firm value could be affected by other blockhoklers that are not part of the management/family group.LLSV study the 20 largest firms in each of 27 wealthy economies and report that the cash flow rights held by the largest blockholder are positively related to firm value. They find no relation between Q and a separation in the control rights and cash flow rights held by the largest blockholder. Claessens et al. (2002) study a large set of firms from eight East Asian emerging economies and also find that the cash flow rights held by the largest blockholder are positively related to value.Additionally, they find that a difference in the control rights and cash flow rights held by the largest blockholder is negatively related to firm value.This paper builds on previous work relating ownership structure to finn value in several ways. First, in all of my sample firms, I explicitly account for the effect of management group (and its femily) ownership and whether there is a large nonmanagement blockholder present in the ownership structure. Since it is the management group that actually administers a firm, the reduction in value from potentially costly agency problems may be even worse when the management group has sufficient control to exploit minority shareholders and there is no large nonaffiliated blockholder to constrain it from doing so. Backman (1999) details many examples of listed emerging market firms engaging in sometimes egregious expropriation of minority shareholders through related-party transactions.Second,because not every emerging market has identical extemal corporate governance features, I test whether any valuation effects associated with ownership structure are more pronounced when shareholder protections are the weakest.Finally, I expand considerably the number of less developed countries in which ownership and valuation are studied and use a broad cross section of firms from each.For all of my sample firms, I trace out ultimate ownership, which includes both directly and indirectly held control and cash flow rights. I enqiloy a broad definition of management group ownership, consisting of a firm's officers, directors, and top-level managers, as well as their family members. I find that management group blockholdings of control (i.e., voting) rights average 30% across my sample. I also group non-management blockholders into various categories.Interestingly, I find that the control rights blockholdings of other shareholders not affiliated with management average almost 20%, which indicates that large non-management blockholders may play an important corporate governance role in emerging market firms. Managers and their families are the largest blockholder in two-thirds of sample firms, consistent with Claessens et al. (2002) and La Portaet al. (1999). I also find that managers make extensive use of pyramid ownership structures in all sample countries and that managers of Ladn American firms fiequently use shares with superior voting rights to further increase the control rightsassodated with their cash flow rights.My valuation analysis contains three sets of tests. The first uses regression models to test the relation between Tbbin's Q and managerial equity holdings, ignoring the effect of the holdings of non-management blockholders. This approach facilitates direct comparison with LLSV (2002) and Claessens et al. (2002). When a management group's control rights exceed its cash fiow rights (because of pyramiding and/or superior voting equity), I find that firm values are lower. I also conduct tests using breakpoints in the level of managerial control and find that managerial control between S% and 20% is negatively related to Q, consistent with the U.S. results of Morck, Shleifer, and Vishny (MSV) (1988). These results support tbe managerial entrenchment hypothesis and indicate that the costs of the private benefits of control are capitalized into share prices in emerging markets.Unlike LLSV (2002) and Claessens et al. (2002), I find no evidence that increases in managerial cash fiow rights affect Tbbin's Q.My second set of tests provides new evidence that laige non-management blockholdeis can reduce the valuation discount associated with expected managerialagency problems in emeiging markets. I categorize firms based on whether the management group is the largest blockholder of control rights and find that management control in the 5% to 20% range is associated with a substantial reduction in Q only when the managrement group is the largest blockholder of control rights. When a larger non-management blockholder is present, management control in the S% to 20% range does not affect firm value. Regressions also show that Q is positively related to the evel of non-management control and to whether a non-management entity is the largest blockholder of control rights.In my third set of tests, I present evidence that the valuation impact of pyramid stiuctures and non-management blockholdings depends on the level of shareholder protection in a country.When managers have control rights that exceed their proportional ownership, firm values are significantly lower in countries with low shareholder protection. These findings suggest that external govemance mechanisms play a role in restraining managers who do not bear the full cash flow consequences of exercising their private benefits of control. I also find that the presence of laige non-management blockholders is more positively related to value in low protection countries. One interpretation of this result is that nonmanagement blockholders are a substitute for formal external governance mechanisms.The next section of the papa describes the sample selection process and the ownership variables used in the paper. Section UI discusses the methodology and describes the results. Section IV conducts tests of robustness and Section V concludes.ConclusionThis paper investigates the relation between ownership structure and firm value across 1433 firms from 18 emerging markets. I depart from previous crosscountry research on ownership and valuation by explicitly examining management and family ownership across all of my sample firms and whether large nonmanagement blockholders provide monitoring. I also investigate whether the relation between ownership and value depends upon the level of external shareholder protection in a country.This paper contains several interesting results. First, I find that management group control in excess of its proportional ownership is negatively related to Tobin'sQ in emerging markets. Managerial control in the 5% to 20% range is also negatively related to Q. These results indicate that investors discount firms with potentially severe managerial agency problems resulting from misaligned incentivesand managerial entrenchment. Second, I provide evidence that large nonmanagement blockholders can mitigate the valuation discount associated with these expected agency problems. Managerial control in the 5% to 20% range is only associated with lower firm values when the management group is also the latgest blockholder. When a larger non-management blockholder is present, managerial control in the 5% to 20% range does not affect firm value. Regressions also show that large non-management blockholdings are positively related to Tobin's Q values.Next, I examine whether the relation between ownership and value depends on the level of shareholder protection in a countiy. When managers have control rights that exceed their proportional ownership, firm values are significantly lower in countries with low shareholder protection. I also find that the relation between large non-management blockholders and value is significantly more positive in low protection countries. These findings suggest that external shareholder protection mechanisms play a role in restraining managerial agency costs. They also indicate that large non-management blockholders may act as a substitute for missing institutional governance mechanisms.Interesting topics for future ownership structure research include identifying the factors that drive the presence of large non-management blockholders and studying why Latin American firms use non-voting equity structures much more frequently than do other emerging market firms.译文新兴市场领域,股权结构与公司价值的关系资料来源: /finkvl/LinsJFQA2003.pdf作者:Karl V. Lins摘要本人通过对1433个来自8个新兴市场样本公司的研究,探索管理层持股和大型非管理层股东持股与公司价值的关系。
2110807233 朱晓倩
股权结构与公司绩效的关系——基于金融行业上市公司的实证研究摘要:股权结构和公司绩效的关系一直是学术界研究的热点。
本文在国内外股权结构理论和公司治理理论的基础上,以金融行业上市公司为主要研究对象,选取了2007-2010年沪深两市金融行业共37家上市公司的相关数据作为样本进行实证分析。
通过对股权属性和股权集中度的研究发现,金融行业上市公司的法人股比例与公司绩效存在着显著的正相关性,流通股比例则与公司绩效呈显著负相关;而股权集中度与公司绩效之间的相关性并不突出。
关键词:股权结构公司绩效金融行业上市公司The Relationship of Ownership Structure andCorporate Performance-an Empirical Study of Listed Companies from theFinancial SectorAbstract:The relationship of ownership structure and corporate performance has been the focus of academic research for a long time. In this paper, based on the theory of ownership structure and corporate performance at home and abroad, we choose the financial sector as the main subject and select 37 listed companies in Shanghai and Shenzhen Stock Market from 2007 to 2010 as the sample for empirical analysis. Through the study of ownership attributes and concentration, we find that the proportion of corporate shares has a significant positive correlation with the corporate performance, and the proportion of tradable shares has a significant negative correlation, while there is not a significant relationship between the ownership concentration and corporate performance in listed companies from the financial sector.Key Words:Ownership Structure Corporate Performance Financial Sector Listed Companies众所周知,中国的上市公司长期以来普遍存在着国有股“一股独大”的现象。
资本结构、股权结构与公司绩效外文翻译
中文2825字1868单词外文文献:Capital structure, equity ownership and firm performanceDimitris Margaritis, Maria Psillaki 1Abstract:This paper investigates the relationship between capital structure, ownership structure and firm performance using a sample of French manufacturing firms. We employ non-parametric data envelopment analysis (DEA) methods to empirically construct the industry’s ‘best practice’frontier and measure firm efficiency as the distance from that frontier. Using these performance measures we examine if more efficient firms choose more or less debt in their capital structure. We summarize the contrasting effects of efficiency on capital structure in terms of two competing hypotheses: the efficiency-risk and franchise value hypotheses. Using quantile regressions we test the effect of efficiency on leverage and thus the empirical validity of the two competing hypotheses across different capital structure choices. We also test the direct relationship from leverage to efficiency stipulated by the Jensen and Meckling (1976) agency cost model. Throughout this analysis we consider the role of ownership structure and type on capital structure and firm performance.Firm performance, capital structure and ownershipConflicts of interest between owners-managers and outside shareholders as well as those between controlling and minority shareholders lie at the heart of the corporate governance literature (Berle and Means, 1932; Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Shleifer and Vishny, 1986). While there is a relatively large literature on the effects of ownership on firm performance (see for example, Morck et al., 1988; McConnell and Servaes, 1990; Himmelberg et al., 1999), the relationship between ownership structure and capital structure remains largely unexplored. On the other hand, a voluminous literature is devoted to capital structure and its effects on corporate performance –see the surveys by Harris and Raviv (1991) and Myers (2001). An emerging consensus that comes out of the corporate governance literature (see Mahrt-Smith, 2005) is that the interactions between capital structure and ownership structure impact on firm values. Yet theoretical arguments alone cannot unequivocally predict these relationships (see Morck et al., 1988) and the empirical evidence that we have often appears to be contradictory. In part these conflicting results arise from difficulties empirical researchers face in obtaining direct measures of the magnitude of agency costs that are not confounded by factors that are beyond the control of management (Berger and Bonaccorsi di Patti, 2006). In the remainder of this section we briefly review the literature in this area focusing on the main hypotheses of interest for this study.Firm performance and capital structureThe agency cost theory is premised on the idea that the interests of the company’s managers and its shareholders are not perfectly aligned. In their seminal paper Jensen and Meckling (1976) emphasized the importance of the agency costs of equity arising from the separation of ownership and control of firms whereby managers tend to maximize their own utility rather than the value of the firm. These conflicts may occur in situations where managers have incentives to take1来源:Journal of Banking & Finance , 2010 (34) : 621–632,本文翻译的是第二部分excessive risks as part of risk shifting investment strategies. This leads us to Jensen’s (1986) “free cash flow theory”where as stated by Jensen (1986, p. 323) “the problem is how to motivate managers to disgorge the cash rather than investing it below the cost of capital or wasting it on organizational inefficiencies.”Thus high debt ratios may be used as a disciplinary device to reduce managerial cash flow waste through the threat of liquidation (Grossman and Hart, 1982) or through pressure to generate cash flows to service debt (Jensen, 1986). In these situations, debt will have a positive effect on the value of the firm.Agency costs can also exist from conflicts between debt and equity investors. These conflicts arise when there is a risk of default. The risk of default may create what Myers (1977) referred to as an“underinvestment”or “debt overhang”problem. In this case, debt will have a negative effect on the value of the firm. Building on Myers (1977) and Jensen (1986), Stulz (1990) develops a model in which debt financing is shown to mitigate overinvestment problems but aggravate the underinvestment problem. The model predicts that debt can have both a positive and a negative effect on firm performance and presumably both effects are present in all firms. We allow for the presence of both effects in the empirical specification of the agency cost model. However we expect the impact of leverage to be negative overall. We summarize this in terms of our first testable hypothesis. According to the agency cost hypothesis (H1) higher leverage is expected to lower agency costs, reduce inefficiency and thereby lead to an improvement in firm’s performance.Reverse causality from firm performance to capital structureBut firm performance may also affect the choice of capital structure. Berger and Bonaccorsi di Patti (2006) stipulate that more efficient firms are more likely to earn a higher return for a given capital structure, and that higher returns can act as a buffer against portfolio risk so that more efficient firms are in a better position to substitute equity for debt in their capital structure. Hence under the efficiency-risk hypothesis (H2), more efficient firms choose higher leverage ratios because higher efficiency is expected to lower the costs of bankruptcy and financial distress. In essence, the efficiency-risk hypothesis is a spin-off of the trade-off theory of capital structure whereby differences in efficiency, all else equal, enable firms to fine tune their optimal capital structure.It is also possible that firms which expect to sustain high efficiency rates into the future will choose lower debt to equity ratios in an attempt to guard the economic rents or franchise value generated by these efficiencies from the threat of liquidation (see Demsetz, 1973; Berger and Bonaccorsi di Patti, 2006). Thus in addition to a equity for debt substitution effect, the relationship between efficiency and capital structure may also be characterized by the presence of an income effect. Under the franchise-value hypothesis (H2a) more efficient firms tend to hold extra equity capital and therefore, all else equal, choose lower leverage ratios to protect their future income or franchise value.Thus the efficiency-risk hypothesis (H2) and the franchise-value hypothesis (H2a) yield opposite predictions regarding the likely effects of firm efficiency on the choice of capital structure. Although we cannot identify the separate substitution and income effects our empirical analysis is able to determine which effect dominates the other across the spectrum of different capital structure choices.Ownership structure and the agency costs of debt and equity.The relationship between ownership structure and firm performance dates back to Berle andMeans (1932) who argued that widely held corporations in the US, in which ownership of capital is dispersed among small shareholders and control is concentrated in the hands of insiders tend to underperform. Following from this, Jensen and Meckling (1976) develop more formally the classical owner-manager agency problem. They advocate that managerial share-ownership may reduce managerial incentives to consume perquisites, expropriate shareholders’wealth or to engage in other sub-optimal activities and thus helps in aligning the interests of managers and shareholders which in turn lowers agency costs. Along similar lines, Shleifer and Vishny (1986) show that large external equity holders can mitigate agency conflicts because of their strong incentives to monitor and discipline management.In contrast Demsetz (1983) and Fama and Jensen (1983) point out that a rise in insider share-ownership stakes may also be associated with adverse ‘entrenchment’effects that can lead to an increase in managerial opportunism at the expense of outside investors. Whether firm value would be maximized in the presence of large controlling shareholders depends on the entrenchment effect (Claessens et al., 2002; Villalonga and Amit, 2006; Dow and McGuire, 2009). Several studies document either a direct (e.g., Shleifer and Vishny, 1986; Claessens et al., 2002; Hu and Zhou, 2008) or a non-monotonic (e.g., Morck et al., 1988; McConnell and Servaes, 1995; Davies et al., 2005) relationship between ownership structure and firm performance while others (e.g., Demsetz and Lehn, 1985; Himmelberg et al., 1999; Demsetz and Villalonga, 2001) find no relation between ownership concentration and firm performance.Family firms are a special class of large shareholders with unique incentive structures. For example, concerns over family and business reputation and firm survival would tend to mitigate the agency costs of outside debt and outside equity (Demsetz and Lehn, 1985; Anderson et al., 2003) although controlling family shareholders may still expropriate minority shareholders (Claessens et al., 2002; Villalonga and Amit, 2006). Several studies (e.g., Anderson and Reeb, 2003a; Villalonga and Amit, 2006; Maury, 2006; King and Santor, 2008) report that family firms especially those with large personal owners tend to outperform non-family firms. In addition, the empirical findings of Maury (2006) suggest that large controlling family ownership in Western Europe appears to benefit rather than harm minority shareholders. Thus we expect that the net effect of family ownership on firm performance will be positive.Large institutional investors may not, on the other hand, have incentives to monitor management (Villalonga and Amit, 2006) and they may even coerce with management (McConnell and Servaes, 1990; Claessens et al., 2002; Cornett et al., 2007). In addition, Shleifer and Vishny (1986) and La Porta et al. (2002) argue that equity concentration is more likely to have a positive effect on firm performance in situations where control by large equity holders may act as a substitute for legal protection in countries with weak investor protection and less developed capital markets where they also classify Continental Europe.We summarize the contrasting ownership effects of incentive alignment and entrenchment on firm performance in terms of two competing hypotheses. Under the ‘convergence-of-interest hypothesis’(H3) more concentrated ownership should have a positive effect on firm performance. And under the ownership entrenchment hypothesis (H3a) the effect of ownership concentration on firm performance is expected to be negative.The presence of ownership entrenchment and incentive alignment effects also has implications for the firm’s capital structure choice. We assess these effects empirically. As external blockholders have strong incentives to reduce managerial opportunism they may prefer to use debtas a governance mechanism to control management’s consumption of perquisites (Grossman and Hart, 1982). In that case firms with large external blockholdings are likely to have higher debt ratios at least up to the point where the risk of bankruptcy may induce them to lower debt. Family firms may also use higher debt levels to the extent that they are perceived to be less risky by debtholders (Anderson et al., 2003). On the other hand the relation between leverage and insider share-ownership may be negative in situations where managerial blockholders choose lower debt to protect their non-diversifiable human capital and wealth invested in the firm (Friend and Lang, 1988). Brailsford et al. (2002) report a non-linear relationship between managerial share-ownership and leverage. At low levels of managerial ownership, agency conflicts necessitate the use of more debt but as managers become entrenched at high levels of managerial ownership they seek to reduce their risks and they use less debt. Anderson and Reeb (2003) find that insider ownership by managers or families has no effect on leverage while King and Santor (2008) report that both family firms and firms controlled by financial institutions carry more debt in their capital structure.外文翻译:资本结构、股权结构与公司绩效摘要:本文通过对法国制造业公司的抽样调查,研究资本结构、所有权结构和公司绩效的关系。
公司股权结构与公司绩效:数据来自希腊公司【外文翻译】
外文翻译原文Corporate Ownership Structure and Firm Performance: evidence from Greek firmsMaterial Source:Author:Panayotis Kapopoulos and Sophia LazaretouThe Berle-Means (1932) thesis implies that diffuse ownership adversely affects firm performance.We test this hypothesis by assessing the impact of the structure of ownership on profitability, taking into account the endogeneity of ownership structure and modelling separately inside and outside ownership.Table 3 presents the result s from the model estimation using Tobin’s Q as a firm performance measure when managerial ownership is taken into account. It uses the total sample size (175 firms) and compares OLS estimates to 2SLS estimates. Table 4 uses the smaller firm sample size (163 firms) excluding utilities and financial institutions. Focusing on OLS estimates for the profitability equation, we note that profitability is always statistically dependent on at least one measure of ownership structure. The regression coefficient of the fraction of shares owned by important outside investors takes a positive sign and is statistically significant. This implies that outside investor shareholdings affect Tobin’s Q ratio positively. This finding is consistent with what one would expect: greater ownership concentration by outside investors may lead to superior performance. The second measure of ownership concentration, namely the fraction of shares owned by management, also has a positive effect on performance, although the coefficient is statistically significant at much lower levels of significance (10 per cent or 15 per cent). This result is consistent with the finding that the simple correlation coefficient between the two ownership variables is 0.54. Moreover, the results shown in the tables for the 2SLS estimates confirm the finding for the effect of ownership concentration on profitability. The coefficients of both ownership variables, important SH and managerial SH, have the correct positive sign and are statistically significant either at a much higher (1 per cent) or a lower (10 per cent) level of significance.Another finding shown in Tables 3 and 4 is the negative effect of thedebt-to-assets ratio on profitability. In all OLS and 2SLS estimates,leverage negatively affects profitability. The distribution-to-sales ratio is positive, as expected, but strongly insignificant. Market concentration consistently has a positive effect on profitability. The coefficient of the CR4 concentration index takes a positive sign and is sometimes statistically significant at the 10 per cent level or better. However, when we adopt a Herfindahl indicator, our data do not support this finding. The coefficient, even though it has the correct sign, is everywhere insignificant. The picture is reversed when we estimate equation (1) with 2SLS. Nevertheless, the data do not seem to support the usual finding of industrial organisation studies that profitability is partly driven by industry concentration.One might expect that high profitability leads management to acquire more shares and, therefore, causes managerial shareholdings to be greater. OLS estimates show that Tobin’s Q is empirically significant in explaining the variation in the structure of corporate ownership. In all regressions (of either sample size), the coefficient of Tobin’s Q is positive and significant at a high level of significance. However, the results for the 2SLS equation estimates of the Tobin’s Q cast doubt on this result. The 2SLS estimates are positive but hardly significant (lower than 15 per cent).As Demsetz and Lehn (1985) have shown, the ownership structure of the media industry is more concentrated than that of industries concerning manufacturing, utility and financial firms. We find that the dummy variable Media is positive and significant at 5 per cent (OLS estimate) or 10 per cent (2SLS estimate). In the profitability equation it enters negatively, but it is insignificant. The positive coefficient on media industry suggests that, ceteris paribus, ownership is more concentrated in media firms with non-profit maximising goals relative to firms operating in other industries. In other words, the utility (U) and financial (F) dummies isolate the impact of “systematic regulation”. As shown in the tables, the OLS estimates for U and F dummies have the expected negative sign and are sometimes significant. These findings, however, are not confirmed by 2SLS estimates.Finally, OLS and 2SLS estimates suggest that size does not seem to be able to explain variations in ownership structure. Using the total firm sample size, the coefficient on firm size, as measured by the book value of total assets, is negative as expected, but insignificant. However, the picture changes when we exclude utilities and financial institutions; firm size becomes significant.So far, we have treated only the fraction of shares owned by management as the endogenous component of corporate ownership structure. Equations (1) and (2) are estimated treating important outside investors’ shareholdings as the endogenous variable in equation (2). Tables 5 and 6 report the OLS and 2SLS estimates. As shown, both measures of ownership structure explain variations in Tobin’s Q. However, as OLS and 2SLS estimates reveal, the coefficient of Tobin’s Q is more strongly statistically significant in the ownership structure equation, implying that firm performance as measured by Tobin’s Q has a stronger effect on the fraction of shares owned by important outside investors than it does on managerial shareholdings. Therefore, as the findings suggest, important SH is likely to be more strongly endogenous.The low value of the simple correlation coefficient between Tobin’s Q and the accounting profit rate (0.157) suggests that we cannot consider the two measures of performance to be redundant. Therefore, we can re-estimate equations (1) and (2) using the accounting rate of return as an alternative measure of firm performance in place of Tobin’s Q.We note that the coefficients that link ownership variables to firm profitability are weaker compared with the estimates obtained using Tobin’s Q. Specifically, important shareholdings continue to have a positive and significant (although at a lower than 10 per cent level) effect on profit rate, whereas managerial shareholdings are everywhere insignificant. Moreover, in all estimates of the ownership structure equation (of either sample size), the profit rate positively and significantly affects managerial shareholdings. Overall, the results provide no reason to alter considerably the conclusions we reach concerning theownership–performance relationship.This paper brings together various aspects of corporate finance and firm performance and examines whether variations across firms in observed ownership structures result in systematic variations in observed firm performance in the context of a small European capital market. We test this hypothesis by assessing the impact of the structure of ownership on performance using data for 175 Greek listed firms. We use two measures of performance –namely, Tobin’s Q and the accounting profit rate –and consider two measures of ownership –namely, the fraction of shares owned by management and the fraction of shares owned by important investors. The paper is primarily motivated by a lack of evidence regarding the relationship between ownership structure and firm performance in Greek firms. Moreover, ownership is modelled as multi-dimensional and endogenously determined.Empirical findings indicate that there exists a linear positive relationship between profitability and ownership structure. Both measures of ownership, managerial shareholdings and important shareholdings, positively influence Tobin’s Q.The results suggest that the greater the degree to which shares are concentrated in the hands of outside or inside shareholders, the more effectively management behaviour is monitored and disciplined, thus resulting in better performance. The results from our study also yield evidence for the endogeneity of ownership structure. We find that profitability is a positive predictor of ownership structure measures, suggesting that the coefficient of a single equation model on the ownership–profitability relationship is biased because of its failure to take into account the complexity of interests involved in an ownership structure. On the one side, Greek data reveal a significant positive impact of ownership structure on profitability. On the other side, there exists evidence that superior firm performance leads to an increase in the value of stock options owned by management or large shareholders, which if exercised, would increase their share ownership.We also find that profitability is negatively related to the debt-to-assets ratio. This evidence reveals the existence of reducing effects of the differences between the interest obligations incurred when borrowing took place and the interest rates that prevailed during the ample period. The statistical insignificance of the relationship between profitability and distribution-to-sales ratio indicates that our model fails to expl ain differences in measurements of Tobin’s Q that are caused by accounting artefacts. Lastly, we find that profitability is positively related to market concentration (measured by CR4 concentration ratio). This can be considered either as the result of scale economies in most of the sectors of our sample or as a consequence of the fact that larger firms in markets with oligopoly structure are able to exercise market power. However, when we use the Herfindahl index as a proxy for the degree of concentration, we cannot detect a strongly significant relationship with firm performance.A striking evidence of our empirical analysis is the significant positive relationship found between media dummy and ownership structure. This result, in conjunction with the finding that the media dummy enters negatively the profitability equation (even though it is insignificant), means that firms in the media industry with high “amenity potential” could not be used to produce these non-profit amenities if they were more diffused. This result might explain the recent attemptsof the Greek government to reform the corporate governance legislation so as to forbid concentration of a share above 1 per cent in the hands of the same shareholder. This legal reform aims at excluding chiefly those that undertake the construction of public works from a strict management control of media firms so as to reduce corruption incentives.A caveat is in order. As we have already mentioned, the Athens Stock Exchange reports only the percentage of shares that is either equal or larger than 5 per cent of outstanding shares. According to the current institutional framework, firms do not have the legal obligation to announce changes in voting rights for those owners with a share below 5 per cent. Consequently, the lack of data for equity owners with a share below 5 percent imposes a constraint on our empirical analysis. It causes a discontinuity in the observations used in the construction of the ownership structure variable. A more rigorous definition of that variable would take into account the fraction of shares owned by a firm’s shareholders or management, each of whom owns at least 1 per cent of outstanding shares.Suggestions for further research include the development and estimation of a generalised non-linear model specification. Some authors (Morck et al., 1988; Welch, 2003) have estimated the relationship between managerial share ownership and profitability in the context of a non-linear single equation model. However, they do not control for the possible endogeneity of a firm’s ownership structure. It might be interesting to address the issue of a non-monotonic relationship by developing a non-linear equation model taking into account both endogeneity and non-linearity. Further,the data sample used in this study covers a relatively large number of Greek listed firms for the year 2000. One would expect to calculate the variables for a longer period of two or five years so as to avoid the impact of the business cycle. Data availability is a serious constraint in our analysis. The Athens Stock Exchange started to publish information concerning the changes in voting rights only from 2000. Therefore, it might be informative to replicate the estimates using panel data for some years after 2000. In this case, however, the firm sample would change and the results might not be comparable. Also, firm coverage would be limited, since we require a minimum of a three-year presence for each firm in the sample.译文公司股权结构与公司绩效:数据来自希腊公司资料来源: 作者:Panayotis Kapopoulos and Sophia Lazaretou在Berle 和Means(1932)的论文中提出所有权对企业的绩效产生不利影响。
股权结构与公司业绩外文翻译(可编辑)
股权结构与公司业绩外文翻译外文翻译Ownership Structure and Firm Performance: Evidence from IsraelMaterial Source: Journal of Management and Governance Author: Beni Lauterbach and Alexander Vaninsky1.IntroductionFor many years and in many economies, most of the business activity was conducted by proprietorships, partnerships or closed corporations. In these forms of business organization, a small and closely related group of individuals belonging to the same family or cooperating in business for lengthy periods runs the firm and shares its profits.However, over the recent century, a new form of business organization flourished as non-concentrated-ownership corporations emerged. The modern diverse ownership corporation has broken the link between the ownership and active management of the firm. Modern corporations are run by professional managers who typically own only a very small fraction of the shares. In addition, ownership is disperse, that is the corporation is owned by and its profits are distributed among many stockholders.The advantages of the modern corporation are numerous. It relievesfinancing problems, which enables the firm to assume larger-scale operations and utilize economies of scale. It also facilitates complex-operations allowing the most skilled or expert managers to control business even when they the professional mangers do not have enough funds to own the firm. Modern corporations raise money sell common stocks in the capital markets and assign it to the productive activities of professional managers. This is why it is plausible to hypothesize that the modern diverse-ownership corporations perform better than the traditional “closely held” business forms.Moderating factors exist. For example, closely held firms may issue minority shares to raise capital and expand operations. More importantly, modern corporations face a severe new problem called the agency problem: there is a chance that the professional mangers governing the daily operations of the firm would take actions against the best interests of the shareholders. This agency problem stems from the separation of ownership and control in the modern corporation, and it troubled many economists before e.g., Berle and Means, 1932; Jensen andMeckling, 1976; Fama and Jensen 1983. The conclusion was that there needs to exist a monitoring system or contract, aligning the manager interests and actions with the wealth and welfare of the owners stockholdersAgency-type problems exist also in closely held firms becausethere are always only a few decision makers. However, given the personal ties between the owners and mangers in these firms, and given the much closer monitoring, agency problems in closely held firms seem in general less severe.The presence of agency problems weakens the central thesis that modern open ownership corporations are more efficient. It is possible that in some business sectors the costs of monitoring and bonding the manager would be excessive. It is also probable that in some cases the advantages of large-scale operations and professional management would be minor and insufficient to outweigh the expected agency costs. Nevertheless, given the historical trend towards diverse ownership corporations, we maintain the hypothesis that diverse-ownership firms perform better than closely held firms. In our view, the trend towards diverse ownership corporations is rational and can be explained by performance gains.2. Ownership Structure and Firm PerformanceOne of the most important trademarks of the modern corporation is the separation of ownership and control. Modern corporations are typically run by professional executives who own only a small fraction of the shares.There is an ongoing debate in the literature on the impact and merit of the separation of ownership and control. Early theorists such as Williamson 1964 propose that non-owner managers prefer their owninterests over that of the shareholders. Consequently, non-owner managed firms become less efficient than owner-managed firms.The more recent literature reexamines this issue and prediction. It points out the existence of mechanisms that moderate the prospects of non-optimal and selfish behavior by the manager. Fama 1980, for example, argues that the availability and competition in the managerial labor markets reduce the prospects that managers would act irresponsibly. In addition, the presence of outside directors on the board constrains management behavior. Others, like Murphy 1985, suggest that executive compensation packages help align management interests with those of the shareholders by generating a link between management pay and firm performanceHence, non-owner manager firms are not less efficient than owner-managed firms. Most interestingly, Demsetz and Lehn 1985 conclude that the structure of ownership varies in ways that are consistent with value imization. That is, diverse ownership and non-owner managed firms emerge when they are more worthwhile.The empirical evidence on the issue is mixed see Short 1994 for a summaryPart of the diverse results can be attributed to the difference across the studies in the criteria for differentiation between owner and non-owner manager controlled firms. These criteria, typically based on percentage ownership by large stockholders, are less innocuous and more problematic than initially believed because, as demonstrated by Morck,Shleifer and Vishny 1988 and McConnell and Servaes 1990, the relation between percentage ownership and firm performance is nonlinear. Further, percent ownership appears insufficient for describing the control structure. Two firms with identical overall percentage ownership by large blockholders are likely to have different control organizations, depending on the identity of the large stockholders.In this study, we utilize the ownership classification scheme proposed by Ang, Hauser and Lauterbach 1997. This scheme distinguishes between non-owner managed firms, firms controlled by concerns, firms controlled by a family, and firms controlled by a group of individuals partners. Obviously, the control structure in each of these firm types is different. Thus, some new perspectives on the relation between ownership structure and firm performance might emerge.3. DataWe employ data from a developing economy, Israel, where many forms of business organization coexist. The sample includes 280 public companies traded on the Tel-Aviv Stock Exchange TASE during 1994. For each company we collect data on the 1992?1994 net income profits after tax, 1994 total assets, 1994 equity, 1994 top management remuneration, and 1994 ownership structure. All data is extracted from the companies financial reports except for the classification of firms according to their ownership structure, which is based on the publica tions, “Holdings ofInterested Parties” issued by the Israel Securities Authority, “Meitav Stock Guide,” and “Globes Stock Exchange Yearbook”.The initial sample included all firms traded on the TASE about 560 at the time. However, sample size shrunk by half because: 1 according to the Israeli Security Authority the Israeli counterpart of the US SEC only 434 companies provided reliable compensation reports; 2 147 companies have a negative 1992?94 average net income, which makes them unsuitable for the methodology we employ; and 3 for 7 firms we could not determine the ownership structure.The companies in the sample represent a rich variety of ownership structures, as illustrated in Figure 1. Nine percent of the firms do not have any majority owner. Among majority owned firms, individuals family firms or partnerships of individuals own 72% and the rest are controlled by concerns. About half 49% of the individually-controlled firms are dominated by a partnership of individuals and the rest 51% are dominated by families. Professional non-owner CEOs are found in about 15% of the individually controlled firms.4. Methodology: Data Envelopment AnalysisIn this study, we measure relative performance using Data Envelopment Analysis DEA. Data Envelopment Analysis is currently a leading methodology in Operations Research for performance evaluations see Seiford and Thrall, 1990, and previous versions of it have been usedin Finance by Elyasiani andMehdian, 1992, for example.The main advantage of Data Envelopment Analysis is that it is a parameter-free approach. For each analyzed firm, DEA constructs a “twin” comparable virtual firm consisting of a portfolio of other sample firms. Then, the relative performance of the firm can be determined. Other quantitative techniques such as regression analysis are parametric, that is it estimates a “production function” and assesses each firm performance according to its residual relative to the fitted fixed parameters economy-wide production function. We are not claiming that parametric methods are inadequate. Rather, we attempt a different and perhaps more flexible methodology, and compare its results to the standard regression methodology Findings.The equity ratio variable represents expectation that given the firm size, the higher the investments of stockholders equity, the higher their return net income. Finally, the CEO and top management compensation variables are controlling for the managers’ input. One of our central points is that top managers’ actions and skills affect firm output. Hence, higher pay mangers who presumably are also higher-skill are expected to yield superior profits. Rosen 1982 relates executives’ pay and rank in the organization to their skills and abilities, and Murphy 1998 discusses in de tail the structure of executive pay and its relation to firm’s performance.The DEA analysis and the empirical estimation of the relative performance of different organizational forms are repeated in four separate subsets of firms: Investment companies, Industrial companies, Real-estate companies, and Trade and services companies. This sector analysis controls for the special business environment of the firms and facilitates further examination of the net effect of ownership structure on firm performance.5.Empirical Results The main results of the empirical findings reviewed above are that majority Control by a few individuals diminishes firm performance, and that professional non-owner managers promote performance. The conclusions about individual control and professional management are reinforced by two other findings. First, it appears that firms without professional managers and firms controlled by individuals are more likely to exhibit negative net income.Second, Table IV also presents results of regressions of net income, NET INC, on leverage, size, professional manager dummy, and individual control dummy.6. ConclusionsThe empirical analysis of 280 firms in Israel reveals that ownership structure impacts firm performance, where performance is estimated as the actual net income of the firm divided by the optimal net income given the firm’s inputs. We find that:Out of all organizational forms, family owner-managed firms appearleast efficient in generating profits. When all firms are considered, only family firms with owner managers have an average performance score of less than 30%, and when performance is measured relative to the business sector, only family firms with owner-managers have an average score of less than 50%.2Non-owner managed firms perform better than owner-managed firms. These findings suggest that the modern form of business organization, namely the open corporation with disperse ownership and non-owner managers, promotes performance Critical readers may wonder how come “efficient” and “less-efficient” organizational structures coexist. The answer is that we probably do not document a long-term equilibrium situation. The lower-performing family and partnership controlled firms are likely, as time progresses, to transform into public-controlled non-majority owned corporations.A few reservations are in order. First, we do not contend that every company would gain by transforming into a disperse ownership public firm. For example, it is clear that start-up companies are usually better off when they are closely held. Second, there remain questions about the methodology and its application Data Envelopment Analysis is not standard in Finance. Last, we did not show directly that transforming into a disperse ownership public firm improves performances. Future research should further explore any performance gains from the separation ofownership and control.译文股权结构与公司业绩资料来源:管理治理杂志作者:贝尼?劳特巴赫和亚历山大?范尼斯基多年来,在许多经济体中的大多数商业活动是由独资企业、合伙企业或者非公开企业操作管理的。
上市公司股权结构对公司绩效影响的研究
上市公司股权结构对公司绩效影响的研究作者:胡秋艳朱凤池来源:《企业文化·中旬刊》2014年第03期摘要:本文是基于对有关新疆上市公司股权结构与公司绩效的文献进行了研究后的综述。
以此,增加对新疆的上市公司的了解,并发现新的研究视角,为新疆上司公司治理状况的改进提供建议。
关键词:股权结构;公司绩效“Corporate Governance”被翻译成公司治理或者公司治理结构,在国内的学者的研究文献中大多混用,认为这两个概念的含义是一样的。
吴蓓蕾(2011)认为公司治理结构主要指公司的股权性质、股权结构、以及董事会、监事会结构等。
本文主要从股权结构角度介绍股权结构和公司绩效之间的关系。
公司的股权结构是指公司股东的构成,包括股东的类型及各类股东持股所占比例,股票的集中或分散程度,股东的稳定性,高层管理者的持股比例等。
股权结构是公司治理的基础,不同的股权结构导致不同的公司治理效率,并最终影响公司的财务绩效。
本文经过查阅有关新疆上市公司股权结构与公司绩效相关性的文献,得出新疆上市公司股权结构对公司绩效影响的现状分析,同时指出学者们认为目前新疆上市公司存在的一些治理缺陷,并总结相应的改进建议,这对完善新疆上市公司治理结构,提高公司绩效有一定的参考意义。
一、文献综述(一)国外文献对股权结构与公司绩效关系的研究始于Jensen & Meckling(1976),他们认为经理机会主义取决于其所占公司股份的多少。
在中国大多数上市公司中,政府或法人是大股东,其股权的行使主要通过政府和法人向企业派遣董事和监事,甚至直接任命董事长和总经理,要求企业的重大决策要向政府汇报或经政府批准,对一些特大型国有独资或国有控股企业,还由国务院派遣稽查特派员,监督企业经营者,难免有一些政府行为。
至于中小股东,由于持股份额太小且投机性很强,其进入和退出的行为也很难起到制约经营者的作用。
经理市场的存在或经理更换的压力,是促使经理努力工作的重要原因(Fama,1980)。
外文翻译 公司股权结构对盈余稳健性的影响(中英文)
公司股权结构对盈余稳健性的影响:来自中国的证据The Effects of Corporate Ownership Structure on Earnings Conservatism: Evidence from China原文出处:Asian Journal of Finance & Accounting ISSN 1946-052X 2010, Vol. 2, No. 1: E3译文:本文研究企业的所有制结构对收入保守主义的增量效应,研究中国上市公司的数据。
我们采用的概念有巴苏(1997)保守主义定义盈余稳健性和采用条件的实证模型,Ball和Shivakumar(2005年)来衡量发展程度的盈利保守主义。
我们的实证结果显示,公司的盈利具有较高的非流通股股东有较低的盈余稳健性。
与以前的研究中,这种一致点表明,该公司与国家和集中的所有权结构更可能依赖于私人通信,以减少信息不对称和内部解决代理问题,从而创造一个低的盈余稳健性的需求。
本研究结果有助于我们了解公司的所有权结构的性能影响在新兴市场和后共产主义市场的盈利。
关键词:盈余稳健性,非流通股股东,股权结构,后共产主义研究,股权分置,国家所有制1。
介绍在20世纪90年代,中国发射了上海证券交易所和随后的深圳证券交易所上市。
除了允许国有企业(国有企业)取得外国资本证券交易所的建立,其目的是提高性能的国有企业通过在资本市场的压力和问责制。
然而,由于政治和经济问题及可能的外资收购的地方国有企业,中国政府拒绝了一个完整的企业私有化,并打算保留其立场作为企业的东主,为了抢占资源分配的控制范围内国家(Allen等,2005)。
该国目前有一些共产主义元素和一些适用范围更广共产党党内监督的资本主义分子,从这个意义上我们主要是在未知的水域。
斯洛文尼亚的后共产主义哲学家齐泽克(2010年),中国的资本主义和共产主义,而独特的合成比是不稳定的,一直是广泛成功的实验,已经持续了30年之久。
上市公司股权结构与公司绩效的实证研究【文献综述】
文献综述财务管理上市公司股权结构与公司绩效的实证研究股权结构与公司绩效的关系是近几年来财务理论以至企业理论研究所关注的热点问题之一,之所以引起大家的关注是因为股权结构作为公司治理结构的重要组成部分和基础,其设置状况是否合理对公司运作效率具有决定性的作用。
关于股权结构与公司绩效的研究,目前国内外学者已经进行了大量的理论和实证研究,尽管研究范围和研究方法各不相同,结论也相差甚远,有的甚至截然相反,但对我们研究上市公司股权结构与公司绩效仍有参考意义。
1 理论基础股权结构是公司治理结构的基础,公司治理结构则是股权结构的具体运行形式。
不同的股权结构决定了不同的企业组织结构,从而决定了不同的企业治理结构,最终决定了企业的行为和绩效。
股权结构也即是股份制公司的产权结构。
Demsetz(1988)认为产权结构是一种外生变量,并把企业视为一系列“契约关系的连接”,着力分析企业产权结构、交易费用、委托代理等问题与企业绩效之间的关系。
菲吕博腾、配杰威齐(1972)也指出股权结构反映了一种产权所有制结构,这种产权结构体现为一种行为权力,即表现为所有权(剩余索取权)和控制权(使用权)的关系,而这种关系在市场上表现为一种外部性,在企业内部由于委托代理的原因产生不同的激励机制,从而都会影响企业的绩效。
而委托代理理论对于深入了解股权结构有着重要意义。
2 国外学者对股权结构与公司绩效的关系研究2.1 股权结构与公司绩效、公司治理正相关关系Grossman和Hart(1980)发现由于可能存在的“搭便车”现象,因此分散的股权结构并不有利于股东对管理者实施有效的监督。
他们研究表明在股权结构分散情况下,单个股东缺乏监督公司经营管理、积极参与公司治理和驱动公司价值增长的激励条件。
Hlii和Shen(1988)以盈利能力度量企业经营绩效的研究显示,股权结构对企业绩效的影响是通过战略选择来实现的。
在股权集中的情况下,有利于鼓励公司进行创新活动,而创新活动是企业经营绩效最大化的相关战略。
论企业绩效与股权结构关系_加金富_论企业绩效与股权结构关系
论企业绩效与股权结构关系摘要作为资本市场的主体,企业的绩效一直备受瞩目,而与其相互关联的股权结构以及内部控制质量也越来越受学者们的关注。
对股权结构具有重要影响的股权分置改革部分已完成,由此带来的公司治理结构问题也在逐步完善当中,然而不断变化的股权结构为上市公司带来新挑战的同时,势必会在不同程度上影响企业内部控制的质量,最终决定企业的绩效水平,因此本文针对企业绩效与股权结构关系进行研究,最后提出一系列可行性建议,期望日后对相关企业的发展提供帮助。
关键词:企业绩效;股权结构;治理AbstractAs the main body of the capital market, the performance of enterprises has been attracting more and more attention, and the related ownership structure and internal control quality have also been paid more and more attention by scholars. The reform of non tradable share structure, which has an important influence on the ownership structure, has been completed, and the corporate governance structure has been gradually improved. However, the changing ownership structure will bring new challenges to the listed companies, and will inevitably affect the quality of internal control in different degrees, and ultimately determine the performance level of enterprises. Therefore, this paper aims at the performance and stock of enterprises Finally, a series of feasible suggestions are put forward to help the development of related enterprises in the future.Key words: enterprise performance; equity structure; Governance目录一、前言 1二、相关概念综述1(一)股权结构 1(二)企业绩效 2三、企业绩效与股权结构的关系分析2(一)股权结构与企业绩效间的机理分析2(二)股权结构与公司绩效的关系机制31.激励机制32.监督机制43.控制权机制5四、相关建议5(一)优化股权结构,寻找合适的股权集中度5(二)改善股权结构体系,形成有效的股权制衡机制6(三)健全公司内部控制制度,提高内部控制有效性6(四)配合内部控制与股权结构的协调发展7结论 8参考文献9致谢 10前言在企业绩效管理成分中,股权结构作为一个重要元素,是企业资产构成的重要元素,其中产权作为作为股份的重要特征,决定了企业的组织结构以及盈利等机制,同时对于企业收益也将起到至关重要的作用。
《股权结构对经营绩效的影响国内外文献综述3500字》
股权结构对经营绩效的影响国内外文献综述1 国外研究现状关于股权结构与企业绩效的研究最早出现在1932年伯利和米恩斯的著作《私有产权与现代企业》中,他们探讨了股权分散以及公司产权分离所引起的委托代理问题。
在此之后,学术界开始关注上市公司股权结构与公司绩效之间的关系。
目前,国外学者们对这一问题的研究成果较为丰富,且有不同的见解,主要分为正相关、负相关、不相关和U 型相关四类。
相关研究成果如下:(1)关于股权结构和经营绩效存在正相关关系的研究Berle和Means(1932)[1]在《私有产权与现代企业》中认为,当公司股权集中度处在一个范围之内时,能够有效改善公司的治理结构并提高公司的经营绩效。
Jensen和Meckling(1976)[2]认为公司股东分为内部、外部股东两类,当内部股东持股比例越高,背离价值的最大化成本越低,公司价值就越高。
Yu Cui和Yin Zang(2019)[3]以中国IT上市公司作为研究对象,得出了股权结构和公司绩效之间具有正相关关系的结论。
(2)关于股权结构和经营绩效存在负相关关系的研究Leech和Leahy(1991)[4]发现公司的股权集中度越高,对公司的交易利润率及净资产的增长越起到负面影响。
Fama和Jensen(1997)[5]认为股权集中度的增加会强化股东的控制权,其损害公司利益而为其谋取私人利益的可能增加。
Alexander Abramov和Alexander Radygin(2017)[6]采取计量经济学的方法对俄罗斯114家最大的公司进行研究,得出国家持股会对公司绩效产生负面影响的结论。
(3)关于股权结构和经营绩效存在不显著相关关系的研究Demsetz和Lehn(1985)[7]以1980年美国上市公司作为研究对象,以会计收益率作为衡量企业绩效的指标与股权集中度建立模型,根据实证结果分析得出会计收益率和股权集中度二者之间没有显著的相关关系。
Cheung,Wei(2006)[8]通过从股东调整持股比例的成本角度对公司股权结构与经营绩效的之间的关系研究发现,股权结构与公司经营绩效呈正相关关系。
资本结构、股权结构与公司绩效的外文翻译
Capital Structure and Firm Performance1. IntroductionAgency costs represent important problems in corporate governance in both financial and nonfinancial industries. The separation of ownership and control in a professionally managed firm may result in managers exerting insufficient work effort, indulging in perquisites, choosing inputs or outputs that suit their own preferences, or otherwise failing to maximize firm value. In effect, the agency costs of outside ownership equal the lost value from professional managers maximizing their own utility, rather than the value of the firm. Theory suggests that the choice of capital structure may help mitigate these agency costs. Under the agency costs hypothesis, high leverage or a low equity/asset ratio reduces the agency costs of outside equity and increases firm value by constraining or encouraging managers to act more in the interests of shareholders. Since the seminal paper by Jensen and Meckling (1976), a vast literature on such agency-theoretic explanations of capital structure has developed (see Harris and Raviv 1991 and Myers 2001 for reviews). Greater financial leverage may affect managers and reduce agency costs through the threat of liquidation, which causes personal losses to managers of salaries, reputation, perquisites, etc. (e.g., Grossman and Hart 1982, Williams 1987), and through pressure to generate cash flow to pay interest expenses (e.g., Jensen 1986). Higher leverage can mitigate conflicts between shareholders and managers concerning the choice of investment (e.g., Myers 1977), the amount of risk to undertake (e.g., Jensen and Meckling 1976, Williams 1987), the conditions under which the firm is liquidated (e.g., Harris and Raviv 1990), and dividend policy (e.g., Stulz 1990).A testable prediction of this class of models is that increasing the leverage ratio should result in lower agency costs of outside equity and improved firm performance, all else held equal. However, when leverage becomes relatively high, further increases generate significant agency costs of outside debt –including higher expected costs of bankruptcy or financial distress –arising from conflicts between bondholders and shareholders.1 Because it is difficult to distinguish empirically between the two sources of agency costs, we follow the literature and allow the relationship between total agency costs and leverage to be nonmonotonic.Despite the importance of this theory, there is at best mixed empirical evidence in the extant literature (see Harris and Raviv 1991, Titman 2000, and Myers 2001 for reviews). Tests of the agency costs hypothesis typically regress measures of firm performance on the equity capital ratio or otherindicator of leverage plus some control variables. At least three problems appear in the prior studies that we address in our application. In the case of the banking industry studied here, there are also regulatory costs associated with very high leverage.First, the measures of firm performance are usually ratios fashioned from financial statements or stock market prices, such as industry-adjusted operating margins or stock market returns. These measures do not net out the effects of differences in exogenous market factors that affect firm value, but are beyond management’s control and therefore cannot reflect agency costs. Thus, the tests may be confounded by factors that are unrelated to agency costs. As well, these studies generally do not set a separate benchmark for each firm’s performance that would be realized if agency costs were minimized.We address the measurement problem by using profit efficiency as our indicator of firm performance.The link between productive efficiency and agency costs was first suggested by Stigler (1976), and profit efficiency represents a refinement of the efficiency concept developed since that time.2 Profit efficiency evaluates how close a firm is to earning the profit that a best-practice firm would earn facing the same exogenous conditions. This has the benefit of controlling for factors outside the control of management that are not part of agency costs. In contrast, comparisons of standard financial ratios, stock market returns, and similar measures typically do not control for these exogenous factors. Even when the measures used in the literature are industry adjusted, they may not account for important differences across firms within an industry – such as local market conditions – as we are able to do with profit efficiency. In addition, the performance of a best-practice firm under the same exogenous conditions is a reasonable benchmark for how the firm would be expected to perform if agency costs were minimized.Second, the prior research generally does not take into account the possibility of reverse causation from performance to capital structure. If firm performance affects the choice of capital structure, then failure to take this reverse causality into account may result in simultaneous-equations bias. That is, regressions of firm performance on a measure of leverage may confound the effects of capital structure on performance with the effects of performance on capital structure.We address this problem by allowing for reverse causality from performance to capital structure. We discuss below two hypotheses for why firm performance may affect the choice of capital structure, the efficiency-risk hypothesis and the franchise-value hypothesis. We construct a two-equation structural model and estimate it using two-stage least squares (2SLS). An equation specifying profit efficiency as a function of the 2 Stigler’s argu ment was part of a broader exchange over whether productive efficiency (or X-efficiency) primarily reflects difficulties in reconciling the preferences of multiple optimizing agents – what is today called agency costs –versus “true”inefficiency, or failureto optimize (e.g., Stigler 1976, Leibenstein 1978). firm’s equity capital ratio and other variables is used to test the agency costs hypothesis, and an equation specifying the equity capital ratio as a function of the firm’s profit efficiency and other variables is used to test the net effects of the efficiency-risk and franchise-value hypotheses. Both equations are econometrically identified through exclusion restrictions that are consistent with the theories.Third, some, but not all of the prior studies did not take ownership structure into account. Under virtually any theory of agency costs, ownership structure is important, since it is the separation of ownership and control that creates agency costs (e.g., Barnea, Haugen, and Senbet 1985). Greater insider shares may reduce agency costs, although the effect may be reversed at very high levels of insider holdings (e.g., Morck, Shleifer, and Vishny 1988). As well, outside block ownership or institutional holdings tend to mitigate agency costs by creating a relatively efficient monitor of the managers (e.g., Shleifer and Vishny 1986). Exclusion of the ownership variables may bias the test results because the ownership variables may be correlated with the dependent variable in the agency cost equation (performance) and with the key exogenous variable (leverage) through the reverse causality hypotheses noted aboveTo address this third problem, we include ownership structure variables in the agency cost equation explaining profit efficiency. We include insider ownership, outside block holdings, and institutional holdings.Our application to data from the banking industry is advantageous because of the abundance of quality data available on firms in this industry. In particular, we have detailed financial data for a large number of firms producing comparable products with similar technologies, and information on market prices and other exogenous conditions in the local markets in which they operate. In addition, some studies in this literature find evidence of the link between the efficiency of firms and variables that are recognized to affect agency costs, including leverage and ownership structure (see Berger and Mester 1997 for a review).Although banking is a regulated industry, banks are subject to the same type of agency costs and other influences on behavior as other industries. The banks in the sample are subject to essentially equal regulatory constraints, and we focus on differences across banks, not between banks and other firms. Most banks are well above the regulatory capital minimums, and our results are based primarily on differences at the mar2. Theories of reverse causality from performance to capital structureAs noted, prior research on agency costs generally does not take into account the possibility ofreverse causation from performance to capital structure, which may result in simultaneous-equations bias. We offer two hypotheses of reverse causation based on violations of the Modigliani-Miller perfect-markets assumption. It is assumed that various market imperfections (e.g., taxes, bankruptcy costs, asymmetric information) result in a balance between those favoring more versus less equity capital, and that differences in profit efficiency move the optimal equity capital ratio marginally up or down.Under the efficiency-risk hypothesis, more efficient firms choose lower equity ratios than other firms, all else equal, because higher efficiency reduces the expected costs of bankruptcy and financial distress. Under this hypothesis, higher profit efficiency generates a higher expected return for a given capital structure, and the higher efficiency substitutes to some degree for equity capital in protecting the firm against future crises. This is a joint hypothesis that i) profit efficiency is strongly positively associated with expected returns, and ii) the higher expected returns from high efficiency are substituted for equity capital to manage risks.The evidence is consistent with the first part of the hypothesis, i.e., that profit efficiency is strongly positively associated with expected returns in banking. Profit efficiency has been found to be significantly positively correlated with returns on equity and returns on assets (e.g., Berger and Mester 1997) and other evidence suggests that profit efficiency is relatively stable over time (e.g., DeYoung 1997), so that a finding of high current profit efficiency tends to yield high future expected returns.The second part of the hypothesis –that higher expected returns for more efficient banks are substituted for equity capital –follows from a standard Altman z-score analysis of firm insolvency (Altman 1968). High expected returns and high equity capital ratio can each serve as a buffer against portfolio risks to reduce the probabilities of incurring the costs of financial distress bankruptcy, so firms with high expected returns owing to high profit efficiency can hold lower equity ratios. The z-score is the number of standard deviations below the expected return that the actual return can go before equity is depleted and the firm is insolvent, zi = (μi +ECAPi)/σi, where μi and σi are the mean and standard deviation, respectively, of the rate of return on assets, and ratios for those that were fully owned by a single owner-manager. This may be an improvement in the analysis of agency costs for small firms, but it does not address our main issues of controlling for differences in exogenous conditions and in setting up individualized firm benchmarks for performance.ECAPi is the ratio of equity to assets. Based on the first part of the efficiency-risk hypothesis, firms with higher efficiency will have higher μi. Based on the second part of the hypothesis, a higher μi allows the firm to have a lower ECAPi for a ven z-score, so that more efficient firms may choose lower equity capital ratios.文章出处:Raposo Clara C. Capital Structure and Firm Performance . Journal of Finance. Blackwell publishing. 2005, (6): 2701-2727.资本结构与企业绩效1.概述代理费用不管在金融还是在非金融行业,都是非常重要的企业治理问题。
【经济类论文】国外股权结构和公司绩效关系的研究综述
国外股权结构和公司绩效关系的研究综述“股权结构”一词的英文是“Ownership Structure”,国内有人也将该词译作“所有权结构”,很多文献中将股权结构和所有权结构两词的含义等同。
实际上两者之间有一定的差异,这种差异是源于人们对企业所有者认识的变化。
传统的物质资本至上的逻辑下,企业的所有者是股东,企业经营的目标是满足股东财富最大化的要求。
这样,股权就等同于企业的所有权,股权结构和所有权结构就是同义词。
随着现代企业理论的发展,人们对企业的认识不断深入,企业利益相关者的理论者如布莱尔认为企业是各相关利益主体之间的合约关系,在企业的经营中股东并没有承担企业全部的经营风险,其它主体诸如债权人、职工等也承担了部分剩余风险,公司应实现所有那些事实上投资于企业并承担风险者的目标,(类似于一种社会目标)。
基于这样的认识,所有权结构的范围就比股权结构的范围更大。
笔者在本文中认为股权结构仅指公司中不同类型的股东所持公司股份的比例关系。
有关这方面的研究最早可追溯至Berle和Means(1932)的研究,他们在其名著《现代公司和私有财产》中指出两权(即所有权和控制权)出现了分离,即出现了“所有权与控制权分离”的现象,公司的控制权由经理人员掌握,股东的权益会受到经理人员行使控制权行为的影响,甚至会损害股东的利益,后人将这一论断称为“Berle-Means命题”。
笔者在对这方面的文献回顾时将其分成理论和实证两条主线,同时对每部分进行论述时,按照内部人持股与公司绩效、外部人与公司绩效和股权结构内生性(股权结构与公司价值无关)三条线索进行专题综述。
一、理论研究现状(1)内部人持股与公司绩效①利益收敛假定(covergence-of-interest hypothesis)Jensen和Meckling假设所有外部股份均没有投票权,管理者不论其持股比例如何都享有对企业的控制权,可将其称为所有者--管理者。
Jenson和Meckling通过对所有者--管理者拥有企业100%的剩余要求权时的行为与他向外出售部分要求权时的行为之间的对比,指出随着股票份额的减少,所有者——管理者对企业产出的权利要求也随之减少,这将导致他以额外津贴的形式(如宽敞的办公环境、厚厚的地毯)等去占用大量的公司资源。
外文翻译--股权结构与公司绩效 以印度为例
中文4200字,2650单词,14800英文字符出处:Srivastava A. Ownership Structure and Corporate Performance: Evidence from India[J]. International Journal of Humanities & Social Science, 2011, 7(3):209–233.原文Ownership Structure and Corporate Performance: Evidence from IndiaAuthor: Aman SrivastavaAbstractOwnership structure of any company has been a serious agenda for corporate governance and that of performance of a firm. Thus, who owns the firm’s equity and how does ownership affect firm value has been a topic investigated by researchers for decades. Thus, the impact of ownership structure on firm performance has been widely tackled in various developed markets and more recently in emerging markets, but was less discussed before, in India in recent changing environment. This paper is a moderate attempt to address the relationship of ownership structure of the firm and its performance. It investigates whether the ownership type affects some key accounting and market performance indicators of listed firms. The 98 most actively listed companies on BSE 100 indices of Bombay Stock Exchange of India, which constitute the bulk of trading, were chosen to constitute the sample of the study as of end of 2009-10. The findings indicate the presence of highly concentrated ownership structure in the Indian market. The results of the regression analyses indicate that the dispersed ownership percentage influences certain dimensions of accounting performance indicators (i.e. ROA and ROE) but not stock market performance indicators (i.e. P/E and P/BV ratios), which indicate that there might be other factors (economic, political, contextual) affecting firms performance other than ownership structure. Keywords: Ownership structure, corporate performance, corporate governance, India1. IntroductionOwnership structure of any company has been a serious agenda for corporate governance and that of performance of a firm. Thus, who owns the firm’s equity and how does ownership affect firm value has been a topic investigated by researchers for decades. Thus, the impact of ownership structure on firm performance has been widely tackled in various developed markets and more recently in emerging markets, but was less discussed before, in India in recent changing environment. Though the modern organization emphasizes the divorce of management and ownership; in practice, the interests of group managing the company can differ from the interests of those that supply the capital to the firm. Corporate governance literature has devoted a great deal of attention to the ownership structure of corporations. Shareholders of publicly held corporations are so numerous and small that they are unable to effectively control the decisions of the management team, and thus cannot be assured that the management team represents their interests. Many solutions to this problem have been advanced, as stated previously i.e. the disciplining effect of the takeover market, the positive incentive effects of the management shareholding stake and the benefits of large monitoring shareholders. A different problem, however, arises in firms with large controlling shareholders. Since a large controlling shareholder has both the incentives and the power to control the management team's actions, management's misbehavior is a second order problem when such a large shareholder exists. Instead, the main problem becomes controlling the large shareholder's abuse of minority shareholders. In other words, holders of a majority of the voting shares in a corporation, through their ability to elect and control a majority of the directors and to determine the outcome of shareholders' votes on othermatters, have tremendous power to benefit themselves at the expense of minority shareholders. Thus, the type of owners as well as the distribution of ownership stakes will undoubtedly have an impact on the performance of firms. Most of the empirical literature studying the link between corporate governance and firm performance usually concentrates on a particular aspect of governance, such as board of directors, share holders’ activism, compensation, anti-takeover provisions, investor protection etc. This paper is a moderate attempt to examine the relationship of ownership structure and performance of firms in India.The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 discusses on the literature review, where both theoretical and empirical studies on previous works are looked into. It also incorporates the corporate governance mechanism in India. In section 3, the methodology of this study is considered. Empirical results and discussions are made in section 4, while section 5 concludes the study.2. Literature ReviewThe firm’s equity and how does ownership affect firm value has been a topic investigated by researchers for decades; however, most of the studies in this context are conducted outside of India. The study failed to document any relevant study on the topic in Indian context. Fama and Jensen (1983 a & b) addresses the agency problems and they explained that a major source of cost to shareholders is the separation of ownership and control in the modern corporation. Even in developed countries, these agency problems continue to be sources of large costs to shareholders1.Demstez and Lehn (1985) argued both that the optimal corporate ownership structure was firm specific, and that market competition would derive firms toward that optimum. Because ownership was endogenous to expected performance, they cautioned, any regression of profitability on ownership patterns should yield insignificant results. Morck. (1988) by taking percentage of shares held by the board of directors of the company as a measure of ownership concentration and holding both Tobin’s Q and accounting profit as performance measure of 500 Fortune companies and using piece-wise linear regression, found a positive relation between Tobin’s Q and board ownership ranging from 0% to 5%, a negative relation for board ownership ranging from 5% to 25%, and again a positive relation for the said ownership above 25%. It is argued that the separation of ownership from control for a corporate firm creates an agency problem that results in conflicts between shareholders and managers (Jensen and Meckling, 1976).The interests of other investors can generally be protected through contractual arrangements between the company and concerned stakeholders, leaving shareholders as the residual claimants whose interests can adequately be protected only through the institutions of corporate governance (Shleifer and Vishny, 1997). Loderer and Martin (1997) took shareholding by the insiders (i.e., director’s ownership) as a measure of ownership. Taking the said measure as endogenous variable and Tobin’s Q as performance measure, they found (through simultaneous equation model) that ownership does not predict performance, but performance is a negative predictor of ownership. Steen Thomsen and Torben Pedersen (1997) examine the impact of ownership structure on company economic performance in the largest companies from 12 European nations. According to their findings the positive marginal effect of ownership ties to financial institutions is stronger in the market-based British system than in continental Europe. Cho (1998) found that firm performance affects ownership structure (signifying percentage of shares held by directors), but not vice versa. Jürgen Weigand (2000) documented that (1) the presence of large shareholders does not necessarily enhance profitability, and (2) the high degree of ownership concentrationseems to be a sub-optimal choice for many of the tightly held German corporations. Their results also imply ownership concentration to affect profitability significantly negatively.Their empirical evidence suggests that representation of owners on the board of executive directors does not make a difference. Yoshiro Miwa and Mark Ramseyer (2001) stated with a sample of 637 Japanese firms and confirmed the equilibrium mechanism behind Demstez-Lehn. Demsetz and Villalonga (2001) investigated the relation between the ownership structure and the performance (average Tobin’s Q for five years-1976-80) of the corporations if ownership is made multidimensional and also treated it as an endogenous variable. By using Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) and Two-stage Least Squares (2 SLS) regression model, they found no significant systematic relation between the ownership structure and firm performance. Demsetz and Villalonga (2001), examined the relationship between ownership structure and firm performance of Australian listed companies. Her OLS results suggest that ownership of shares by the top management is significant in explaining the performance measured by accounting rate of return, but not significant ifperformance is measured by Tobin’s Q. However, when ownership is treated as endogenous, the same is not dependent upon any of the performance measures. Lins (2002) investigates whether management ownership structures and large non-management block holders are related to firm value across a sample of 1433 firms from 18 emerging markets .He finds that large non-management control rights block holdings (having more control rights) are positively related to firm value measured by Tobin’s Q. Michael L Lemmon and Karl V Lins (2003) use a sample of 800 firms in eight East Asian countries to study the effect of ownership structure on value during the region’s financial crisis.The crisis negatively impacted firm’s investment opportunities, raising the incentives of controlling shareholders to expropriate minority investors. The evidence is consistent with the view that ownership structure plays an important role in determining whether insiders expropriate minority shareholders. Using a sample of 144 Israeli firms, Beni Lauterbach and Efrat Tolkowsky (2004) find that Tobin's Q is maximized when control group vote reaches 67%. This evidence is strong when ownership structure is treated as exogenous and weak when it is considered endogenous. Christoph Kaserer and Benjamin Moldenhauer (2005) address the question whether there is any empirical relationship between corporate performance and insider ownership. Using a data set of 245 Germen firms for the year 2003 they find evidence for a positive and significant relationship between corporate performance, as measured by stock price performance as well as by Tobin’s Q, and insider ownership. Kapopoulos and Lazaretou (2007) tried the model of Demsetz and Villalonga (2001) for 175 Greek firms for the year 2000 and found that higher firm profitability requires less diffused ownership structure He also provides evidence that large non management block holders can mitigate the valuation discounts associated with the expected agency problem.3. Data and MethodologyThe study aims to explore the disciplinary effect of the market in a context with concentrated ownership structure and weak investor protection. The paper aims to explore if there are dominant certain types of owners of actively listed and traded companies on Indian Stock Exchanges. Further, it investigates whether the ownership type affects some key accounting and market performance indicators of listed firms. It shows that there might be other reasons that have affected the performance of the listed companies of BSE 100, other than ownership structure.The data set consists of detailed trading and financial information and indicators about the 98most actively traded BSE 100 listed companies on the Bombay Stock Exchange of India (BSE) during 2009-2010. The ninety eight companies cover a broad spectrum of sectors or industries totaling 18, which are: Finance, Oil & Gas, Information Technology, Metal, Metal Products & Mining, Capital Goods, FMCG, Transport Equipments, Power, Housing Related, Healthcare, Telecom, Diversified, Chemical & Petrochemical, Miscellaneous, Media & Publishing, Transport Services, Tourism and Agriculture. The details and proportion of these sectors in BSE 100 is given in table 1.The main financial indicators obtained from the companies financial statements included Total Revenues or Turnover, Gross Profit, Net Income or Earnings After Taxes, Current Assets, Fixed Assets, Long Term Debt and Shareholders Equity. Finally, the third subset consists of companies’ stock performance indicators obtained from CMIE PROWESS database including value traded, volume traded, number of transactions, market capitalization, market price as well as some calculated ratios using both CMIE PROWESS database as well as items reported in financial statements of sample companies such as debt to equity ratio, return on equity, return on assets, price earnings ratio and price to book value. The empirical investigation is conducted using known Ordinary Least Square Estimation methodology using both Return on Equity (ROE) and Return on Investment (ROI) variables - representing accounting performance measures, and Price-Earning Ratio (P/E) and Price to Book Value (P/BV) –representing stock market performance measures; separately as dependent variables. The following formula was used for modeling:Yij = α + xff, j + xde,j + xdph,j + xfp,j + xnpi,j + xnpni,j + ε (i)Where ε ~ ND (0, σ2)Yij : i corresponds to ROE, ROI, P/E or P/B for company j (j=1...98)xff, j : represents the percentage of free float in company j capital structure,xde,j : represents the debt to equity ratio for company j,xdph,j and xfp,j : represents the domestic promoter and foreign promoter holding in the companyxnpi,j and xnpni,j : represents non promoter institutional and non promoter non institutional holding of the company.The independent variables are represented by the percentage of Free Floated shares (FF), Debt to Equity ratio (D/E) and four variables representing promoters and non promoters stake representing the ownership structure in sampled companies, namely; Tables (2) and (3), (4) and (5) in the appendix summarize the regression analysis.4. Results and analysisThe sampled companies of BSE 100 were analyzed on the basis of their free floats and the findings are given below in table 2. Table 2 clearly depict that majority of the sampled companies have less than 75% of the free float. Even 13% companies have a free float of less than 25%. Only 13% of the companies have a free float of greater than 75%. Table three gives the details about the ownership structure of the sampled firms. Data clearly depicts that the stake of Indian promoters I the sampled company varies from 0% to 99% with a average holding of 41%. That means on an average the sampled companies are dominated by Indian promoter’s holdings. While the average foreign promoters holding is just 7.51%. That clearly confirms the belief that the Indian companies are dominated by families and promoter’s stakes. Data related with debt equity profile of sampled companies is givenThe results clearly indicates that majority of the sampled companies are in first category of 0-2 which clearly depicts that the majority of the sampled companies are not highly levered.Performance measures in the paper are represented by two sets of variables accounting measures are ROA and ROE while the market measures are P/E and P/BV ratio. Table five depicts that average ROE, ROA, P/E and P/BV values are 17.36%, 12.77%, 34.8 and 3.8 respectively.The results of OLS regression analysis are given in table 6 below. The empirical results reflect at 5% level of significance the ownership characteristic does not reflect any relationship with either accounting performance measures ROA and ROE or show any significant relationship between ownership structure and stock market indicators P/E and P/BV ratios, as shown in Table (6) below. But at 10% level of significance all sampled variables shows significant relationship with ROA, ROE, P/E and P/BV for performance of any company. Insert table (6) about here5. Findings and ConclusionThe significance of ownership characteristics and accounting performance measures i.e. ROA and ROE could be explained by the fact that the fundamental evaluation of companies, measured by, its financial indicators such as (ROA and ROE) are the most important factors used by investors in India to assess company’s performance. In India, althou gh earlier investors have culturally placed more emphasis on accounting performance measures, not stock market indicators, due to the inactivity and stagnation of the stock market for a long period (till early 1990’s). Furthermore, Indian investors always favored payment of dividends rather than stock price appreciation, due to inactivity of market. Accordingly, the dividends yield paid by Indian companies are always very high (10%-13%) compared to other emerging and developed markets (3%-5%). Thus the author did not consider dividend yield in the stock market indicators since it will be a distorted measure since issuers in India always pay a high dividends yield, sometimes, irrespective of earnings, since they are valued by investors according to dividends not price appreciation. Furthermore, the type of ownership had an insignificant impact on stock market performance measures, which might imply that the stock performance was mainly affected by economic and market conditions rather than ownership concentration. Furthermore, the results could be related to the market inefficiency of the Indian stock market, given its small and thin characteristics, as well as the lack of prompt disclosure by listed companies, even the active ones, at the Indian stock market. Stock prices therefore may not appropriately reflect the costs and benefits of diversification as shown.References[1]Beni Lauterbach, and Efrat Tolkowsky, 2004, “Market Value Maximizing Ownership Structure when Investor Protection is Weak”, Discussion Paper No. 8-200[2]Cho M H (1998), “Ownership Structure, Investment, and the Corporate Value: An Empirical Analysis”,Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 47, No. 1, pp. 103-121.[3]Demsetz H and Lehn K (1985), “The Structure of Corporate Ownership: Causes and Consequences”,Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 93, No. 6, pp. 1155-1177[4]Demsetz H and Villalonga B (2001), “Ownership Structure and Corporate Performance”, Journal of Corporate Finance, V ol. 7, No. 3, pp. 209-233.[5]Erik Lehmann en Jurgen Weigand, Does the governed corporation perform better Governance structures and corporate performance in Germany, European Finance Review, 2000, no. 4, p. 157–195.[6] Fama, E and Jensen, M, 1983a, 1983b. Separation of ownership and control, Journal ofLaw &Economics 26, 301-325 and 327-349.[7]Jensen, M and Meckling, W, 1976. Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305-360.[8]Kapopoulas P and Lazaretou S (2007), “Corporate Ownership Structure and Firm Performance:Evidence from Greek Firms”, Corporate Governance: An International Review,V ol. 15, No. 2, pp. 144-158.[9]Kaserer Christoph, and Benjamin Moldenhauer, 2005, “Insider Ownership and Corporate Performance -Evidence from Germany”, Working Paper”, Center for Entrepreneurial and Financial Studies (CEFS) and Department for Financial Management and Capital Market[10]Lins, K, 2000, Equity Ownership and Firm Value in Emerging Markets, Working paper, University of Utah.[11]Loderer C and Martin K (1997), “Executive Stock Ownership and Performance Tracking Faint Traces”,Journal of Financial Economics, V ol. 45, No. 2, pp. 595-612.[12]Michael L Lemmon, and Karl V Lins, 2003, “Ownership Structure, Corpora te Governance and Firm Value: Evidence from the East Asian Financial Crisis” The Journal of Finance, Vol LVIII No. 4, August 2004[13]Miwa Yoshiro, and Mark Ramseyer, 2001, “Does ownership matter?” Discussion Paper, University of Tokyo[14]Morck, R, Shleifer, A, and Vishny, R, 1988. Management Ownership and Market Valuation: An Empirical Analysis, Journal of Financial Economic 20, 293-315.[15]Pedersen,T and Thompson, S, 1997, European Patterns of Corporate Ownership: A twelve country study, Journal of International Business Studies, 759-778[16]Shleifer, A and Vishny, R, 1997. A survey of corporate governance. Journal of Finance 52, 737-783.译文股权结构与公司绩效: 以印度为例资料来源: 人文和社会科学国际性杂志作者: Monir Zaman摘要任何一家公司的股权结构已经成为公司监管与公司绩效的重要事项。
外文翻译---所有权组织和企业绩效
所有权组织和企业绩效Kang, David L.; Sørensen, B..Annual Review of Sociology, 1999, Vol.25: p121.最近,组织社会学的工作,对如何理解现代公共机构中治理系统的某些功能对公司的重要成果的影响取得了相当大的进展。
企业人员的功能背景,局外人的董事比例,主席及行政总裁职位分离,和在公司发现的社会网络已被用来预测结果,如企业多样化政策,以及使用多部门组织形式。
这项研究已普遍淡化在公司治理中所有权的作用,和假设所有权和控制权得到有效的分离。
相比之下,金融经济的研究继续所有权在控制公司中的作用,尽管这种研究的传统已就组织之间的所有权与经营绩效关系产生非常不同的结果。
所有制组织研及其对工作成果影响的研究不能完全交由财政经济研究。
关于谁控制了资金的使用和这个控制如何影响社会创造和分配财富的研究,一直是知识探索的重要防线,始发于马克思。
运用更广泛和更灵活的方法对个人和企业的财产关系进行研究,也许能对现代资本主义企业的分配效率和结果提供重要的见解。
目前,社会学对这一调查线索的实际和潜在的贡献就显得尤为重要,并因此及时地评估什么是已知的什么是未知的,关于所有制组织对公司绩效的影响。
我们提出了一种基于所有制类型的方法,在决定公司的所有权成果中作为一个主要的组织变量。
在组织社会学和经济学文献中,现代企业往往被看作是一个具有四个主要演员的大机构:股东,董事,高层管理人员和其他管理人员和职工。
股东们认为是业主。
他们提供金融资本和接收来自公司的业务合同的经济回报的承诺。
董事作为该公司的受托人,可以批准一定的策略和投资决策,但其主要责任是雇用和解雇高层管理人员的受托人。
企业经营管理人员,他们行使大多数商业决策并监督和聘请工人。
职工开展活动,创建企业的产量。
这个现代企业形象准确地反映了许多大型的美国经济中占主导地位的公营机构组织。
然而,许多其他公司的方式是进行合并两个或多个组织:业主可同时投资和管理,工人可能是业主,管理人员有可能获得较大份额的所有权等等。
外文翻译--股权结果与公司绩效一个描述性探讨
外文题目:Ownership Structure,Corporate Performance And Failure:Evidence From Panel Data ofEmerging Market The Case of Jordan出处:Corporate Ownership & Control作者:Rami Zeitun原文:2. Ownership Structure and Firm Performance: a Descriptive Discussion2.1 Ownership Structure (Mix) and Firm PerformanceSince the establishment of the ASE in the 1970s,the number of listed companies,trading volume,and total market capitalisation have increased drastically.Table 1 reports the ownership structure of listed companies by sectors.Despite its privatisation program,the government still holds a large stake in Media,Utility and Energy,and Steel,Mining and Heavy Engineering companies (43.20%,33.70 %,and 22.04 %,respectively) because they are considered strategic industries.Institutional ownership is very high in transportation,real estate,and trade and commercial services and rental,and communication (44.80%,44.00%,and 36.89%,respectively).Individual citizens as a group are the largest shareholder of Educational Services,Medical Pharmacies,Textiles and Clothing,and Construction and Engineering.The largest foreign ownership stakes are in Steel,Mining and Heavy Engineering,followed by Tobacco (16.05% and 13.41%,respectively),foreign ownership is also high in the Insurance sector.Table 2 presents the basic statistics of the ownership structure for defaulted and non-defaulted firms.The individual (citizen) owns an average of 51.42 percent of defaulted firms,a figure which is larger than 45.36 percent in non-defaulted firms.The fractions of government and foreigner ownership have their lowest median in the defaulted firms,0.58 and 1.21 percent respectively,compared with 2.37 and 4.20 percent in non-defaulted firms for government and foreigner respectively.There are several notable differences.First of all,defaulted firms have a lowermedian of government ownership.Also,the median of institutional ownership is lower,as is the median of foreigner ownership.Table 2 suggests that Jordanian firms with government,institutional,and foreign ownership have a lower risk of failure (default) (in this analysis,we will concentrate on the joint factor of Arab and foreign ownership rather than taking each one separately as both of them are considered foreign owners).The next section discusses the characteristics of defaulted firms in terms of ownership concentration.Table 1. Ownership Structure by Sector2.2 Ownership ConcentrationIt was established in that the ownership structure in the ASE is highly concentrated (the median largest shareholder in Jordan is large by Anglo-American standards but within the range of those in France and Spain,20 and 34 percent respectively.Table 3 sheds more light on the ownership concentration for Jordanian companies by sectors using five measures of ownership concentration across all firm-years.The largest shareholder (C1) owns the highest percentage in the Hotel and Tourism sector and Media sector (35.32 percent and 35.50 percent respectively).The largest shareholder C1 owns the lowest percentage in the Educational sector (7.86 percent).The data also reveals that there is a substantial variation across firms and sectors in ownership concentration.Given that the holding of the largest shareholder (C1) is so large,the other shareholders are small.As shown in Table 3,the cumulative percentage of ownership tapers rapidly,and there is little difference between C3 and C5 in all sectors.The average of C3 is highest in the Media sector followed by the Transportation sector with 49.53 percent and 45.94 percent in each sector respectively.The Educational, Medical Pharmacy,Tobacco,and Paper,Glass,and Packaging sectors have the lowest ownership concentration in terms of the largest five shareholders (C5),compared with highest stake in Transportation,Media,and Trade,Commercial Services,Rental and Communication.The variation could relate to the capital required in these sectors,and also the importance of the sector,often there is high state ownership in sectors regarded as strategic.Table 4 presents the basic statistics of ownership concentration for defaulted and non-defaulted firms.Considering the median,the largest shareholder (C1) owns20 percent in the defaulted firms, a figure which is larger than the 18.86 percent in the non-defaulted firms.The largest two shareholders (C2) own 29.09 percent in the defaulted firms,a figure which is only marginally larger than 28.60 percent in the non-defaulted firms.The other measures of concentration C3,C5,and HERF are all larger in defaulted than non-defaulted firms.The data also reveals that there is a substantial variation across firms in ownership concentration:despite the high average, the largest owner’s value varies between 0 and 100 percent.In this study,we used C5 and HERF indexes as indictors of ownership concentration to investigate whether ownership concentration increased the firm’s performance and contributed to the firm’s defau lt.Table 3. Ownership Concentration by Sector:Cumulative percentage of shares controlled by4. Empirical ResultsThe analysis of the results is presented here in separate subsections.It begins with an analysis of the effect of ownership structure on corporate performance,where ownership concentration and mix are used in the analysis.The analysis then moves to examining the effect of ownership structure (mix and concentration) on corporate failure.This includes an analysis of the statistical significance of each variable.The random-effects model is used to examine the effect of ownership structure and control for the effect of industrial sectors on corporate performance.4.1 Ownership Structure and Corporate PerformanceIn order to explore the appropriateness of a random-effects model,a Breusch-Pagan Lagrange Multiplier test is conducted to determine the overall significance of these effects.According to the Breusch-Pagan test the null hypothesis is that random components are equal to zero.This test also provided support for the Generalized Least Squares (GLS) over a pooled Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression.In all models,the Breusch-Pagan Lagrange Multiplier test supported the use of the random-effects model.Also,the Hausman test failed to reject the null hypothesis of no difference between the coefficients of the random- and the fixed-effects models.For example,the Chi2(4) = 0.36,P=0.98 and Chi2(4) = 3.4,P=0.49 for Tobin’s Q and MBVR,respectively.Our model also contains time-invariant variables which cannot be estimated using the fixed-effects model.The overall goodness of fit (R2) for the random-effects model,using both ownership mix and concentration and industrial sector variables,is greater than the goodness of fit for the random-effects model using only ownership concentration.A general test for serial autocorrelation in panel data has been conducted using the test developed by Wooldridge (2002).The null hypothesis is that there is no serial autocorrelation for the data examined.The hypothesis is strongly accepted as ((F1,134) =0.847,P=0.3591).Therefore,our models do not have a serialautocorrelation.The overall significance of the models was tested using the Wald test,which has a Chi-square (2χ) distribution under the null hypothesis that all the exogenous variables are equal to zero.For all models,the value of the 2χstatistic is significant at least at the 1 % level of significance using ROA.The estimation results of Equation (1) are presented in Table 5 and Table 6 using the random-effects model.Table 7 and Table 8 report the results for the estimation of Equation 2.To examine the robustness of our results,the model included dummy variables to control for industry effects,and the results are reported in Appendix 1.Appendix 2 and Appendix 3 report the result of the cross-sectional analysis for the matched sample to provide more evidence on the effect of ownership structure on corporate performance.The regression model using price per share to earnings per share,ROE,is not significant and,hence,is not reported using the panel data analysis.4.1.1 Ownership Concentration ResultsFrom Hypothesis 1,the variables representing ownership concentration are expected not to have any significant impact on corporate performance.Two variables are used,C5 and HERF.From the regression results in Table 5,the variable C5 was found to have a negative and significant impact on ROA at the 10% level of significance,while it has a positive and significant impact on MBVR.The estimated coefficient of the HERF indicates that it does not have a significant impact on any measure of firm performance or value.Neither the HERF nor the C5 have any significant impact on Tobin’s Q (although the sign of the coefficient was positive in both equations).The result for Tobin’s Q and MBVR are more robust as proved by the R-square and Waled test.Hypothesis 1 is thus rejected as C5 is significantly different from zero in regressions of ROA and MBVR.As concentration is immensely different from industry to industry,this gives rise to the potential for industry effects of ownership concentration on a firm’s value(see Table 4).It can be argued that the effect of ownership concentration may be different from one industry to another.To control for potential industry effects,15 industrial dummy variables were taken and Equation (1) was re-estimated.The results,reported in Table 6,almost changed the significance of C5.The largest five shareholders,C5,becameinsignificant in ROA,while the significance of C5 increased in MBVR.Furthermore,of the 15 industrial dummy variables,only that for sector 8 was found to have a positive impact on a firm’s performance ROA.Also,all the coefficients of the industrial variables were found to have a negative and significan t impact on a firm’s value measured by Tobin’s Q.It should be noted that the significance of these industrial sectors may imply presence of industry sector.The significant impact of concentration ratios on MBVR supports the Shleifer and Vishny hypothesis (1986) that large shareholders may reduce the problem of small investors and,hence,increase the firm’s performance.The finding of a positive and significant relationship between ownership concentration and corporate performance is consistent with prior research based on advanced capital markets including Hill and Snell (1988,1989),Kaplan and Minton (1994),and Morck,Nakamura and Shivdasani (2000),among others.However,this finding is inconsistent with the result of Wu and Cui (2002) that there is a positive relationship between ownership concentration and accounting profits (indicated by ROA),but consistent with the result of Leech and Leahy (1991) and Mudambi and Nicosia (1998).The insignificant result for concentration variable in the Tobin’s Q equation cou ld suggest that the Jordanian equity market is inefficient (or there could be other factors that affect the market performance measure,which were missed in our models).These results are consistent with Abdel Shahid (2003),that ROA is the most important factor used by investors rather than the market measure of performance.外文题目:Ownership Structure,Corporate Performance And Failure:Evidence From Panel Data ofEmerging Market The Case of Jordan出处:Corporate Ownership & Control作者:Rami Zeitun译文:2.股权结果与公司绩效:一个描述性探讨2.1股权结构(组合)和公司绩效美国证券交易所自二十世纪70年代建立以来,在其交易所上市的公司的交易量及市值大幅增加。
多元化、企业业绩与股权结构.doc
多元化、企业业绩与股权结构多元化、企业业绩与股权结构1——对中国上市公司的实证研究赵山肖晟(电子科技大学管理学院) (美国Vanderbilt大学经济系) Corporate Diversification, Firm Performance And Ownership StructureShan Zhao(Management School, UESTC, Jianshe Road, Chengdu, Sichuan, China 610054)Sheng Xiao(Dept.of Economics, Vanderbilt University,Nashville, TN 37235, U.S.A.)Abstract: Based on the data in the Annual Reports (2000) of 942 listed firms in Shanghai and Shenzhen Stock Exchanges, this paper discusses two related issues: the relationship between corporate diversification and firm value and the influence of ownership structure on diversification. We find that the level of diversification is not correlated with firm1感谢香港中文大学商学院提供的资料,四川大学经济学院张静同学在本文数据收集中的工作,华西证券公司研发中心对本文的帮助,四川大学数学学院李竹渝教授对本文初稿的审阅,文责自负。
value (measured by Tobin’Q) and sales growth, but negatively correlated with ROA; diversification is positively correlated with the proportion of legal person shares ratio, and negatively correlated with proportion of state shares ratio. However, in big firms, the relationship between diversification and ownership structure is not statistically significant. This paper also compares the results of our study with those of the relevant studies conducted in other countries.Key Words: corporate diversification, firm performance, firm value, ownership structureJEL Classification: G340, G320, G310作者简介:赵山:男,1974年生,经济学硕士,电子科技大学管理学院教师。
- 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
- 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
- 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。
外文翻译Ownership Structure and Firm Performance:Evidence from IsraelMaterial Source: Journal of Management and GovernanceAuthor: Beni Lauterbach and Alexander Vaninsky1.IntroductionFor many years and in many economies, most of the business activity was conducted by proprietorships, partnerships or closed corporations. In these forms of business organization, a small and closely related group of individuals belonging to the same family or cooperating in business for lengthy periods runs the firm and shares its profits.However, over the recent century, a new form of business organization flourished as non-concentrated-ownership corporations emerged. The modern diverse ownership corporation has broken the link between the ownership and active management of the firm. Modern corporations are run by professional managers who typically own only a very small fraction of the shares. In addition, ownership is disperse, that is the corporation is owned by and its profits are distributed among many stockholders.The advantages of the modern corporation are numerous. It relieves financing problems, which enables the firm to assume larger-scale operations and utilize economies of scale. It also facilitates complex-operations allowing the most skilled or expert managers to control business even when they (the professional mangers) do not have enough funds to own the firm. Modern corporations raise money (sell common stocks) in the capital markets and assign it to the productive activities of professional managers. This is why it is plausible to hypothesize that the modern diverse-ownership corporations perform better than the traditional “closely held”business forms.Moderating factors exist. For example, closely held firms may issue minority shares to raise capital and expand operations. More importantly, modern corporations face a severe new problem called the agency problem: there is a chance that the professional mangers governing the daily operations of the firm would take actions against the best interests of the shareholders. This agency problem stems from theseparation of ownership and control in the modern corporation, and it troubled many economists before (e.g., Berle and Means, 1932; Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Fama and Jensen 1983). The conclusion was that there needs to exist a monitoring system or contract, aligning the manager interests and actions with the wealth and welfare of the owners (stockholders)Agency-type problems exist also in closely held firms because there are always only a few decision makers. However, given the personal ties between the owners and mangers in these firms, and given the much closer monitoring, agency problems in closely held firms seem in general less severe.The presence of agency problems weakens the central thesis that modern open ownership corporations are more efficient. It is possible that in some business sectors the costs of monitoring and bonding the manager would be excessive. It is also probable that in some cases the advantages of large-scale operations and professional management would be minor and insufficient to outweigh the expected agency costs. Nevertheless, given the historical trend towards diverse ownership corporations, we maintain the hypothesis that diverse-ownership firms perform better than closely held firms. In our view, the trend towards diverse ownership corporations is rational and can be explained by performance gains.2. Ownership Structure and Firm PerformanceOne of the most important trademarks of the modern corporation is the separation of ownership and control. Modern corporations are typically run by professional executives who own only a small fraction of the shares.There is an ongoing debate in the literature on the impact and merit of the separation of ownership and control. Early theorists such as Williamson (1964) propose that non-owner managers prefer their own interests over that of the shareholders. Consequently, non-owner managed firms become less efficient than owner-managed firms.The more recent literature reexamines this issue and prediction. It points out the existence of mechanisms that moderate the prospects of non-optimal and selfish behavior by the manager. Fama (1980), for example, argues that the availability and competition in the managerial labor markets reduce the prospects that managers would act irresponsibly. In addition, the presence of outside directors on the board constrains management behavior. Others, like Murphy (1985), suggest that executive compensation packages help align management interests with those of the shareholders by generating a link between management pay and firm performance.Hence, non-owner manager firms are not less efficient than owner-managed firms. Most interestingly, Demsetz and Lehn (1985) conclude that the structure of ownership varies in ways that are consistent with value maximization. That is, diverse ownership and non-owner managed firms emerge when they are more worthwhile.The empirical evidence on the issue is mixed (see Short (1994) for a summary). Part of the diverse results can be attributed to the difference across the studies in the criteria for differentiation between owner and non-owner manager controlled firms. These criteria, typically based on percentage ownership by large stockholders, are less innocuous and more problematic than initially believed because, as demonstrated by Morck, Shleifer and Vishny (1988) and McConnell and Servaes (1990), the relation between percentage ownership and firm performance is nonlinear. Further, percent ownership appears insufficient for describing the control structure. Two firms with identical overall percentage ownership by large blockholders are likely to have different control organizations, depending on the identity of the large stockholders.In this study, we utilize the ownership classification scheme proposed by Ang, Hauser and Lauterbach (1997). This scheme distinguishes between non-owner managed firms, firms controlled by concerns, firms controlled by a family, and firms controlled by a group of individuals (partners). Obviously, the control structure in each of these firm types is different. Thus, some new perspectives on the relation between ownership structure and firm performance might emerge.3. DataWe employ data from a developing economy, Israel, where many forms of business organization coexist. The sample includes 280 public companies traded on the Tel-Aviv Stock Exchange (TASE) during 1994. For each company we collect data on the 1992–1994 net income (profits after tax), 1994 total assets, 1994 equity, 1994 top management remuneration, and 1994 ownership structure. All data is extracted from the companies financial reports except for the classification of firms according to their ownership structure, which is based on the publications, “Holdings of Interested Parties” issued by the Israel Securities Authority, “Meitav Stock Guide,” and “Globes Stock Exchange Yearbook”.The initial sample included all firms traded on the TASE (about 560 at the time). However, sample size shrunk by half because: 1) according to the Israeli Security Authority (the Israeli counterpart of the US SEC) only 434 companiesprovided reliable compensation reports; 2) 147 companies have a negative 1992–94 average net income, which makes them unsuitable for the methodology we employ; and 3) for 7 firms we could not determine the ownership structure.The companies in the sample represent a rich variety of ownership structures, as illustrated in Figure 1. Nine percent of the firms do not have any majority owner. Among majority owned firms, individuals (family firms or partnerships of individuals) own 72% and the rest are controlled by concerns. About half (49%) of the individually-controlled firms are dominated by a partnership of individuals and the rest (51%) are dominated by families. Professional (non-owner) CEOs are found in about 15% of the individually controlled firms.4. Methodology: Data Envelopment AnalysisIn this study, we measure relative performance using Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA). Data Envelopment Analysis is currently a leading methodology in Operations Research for performance evaluations (see Seiford and Thrall, 1990), and previous versions of it have been used in Finance (by Elyasiani andMehdian, 1992, for example).The main advantage of Data Envelopment Analysis is that it is a parameter-free approach. For each analyzed firm, DEA constructs a “twin” comparable virtual firm consisting of a portfolio of other sample firms. Then, the relative performance of the firm can be determined. Other quantitative techniques such as regression analysis are parametric, that is it estimates a “production function” and assesses each firm performance according to its residual relative to the fitted fixed parameters economy-wide production function. We are not claiming that parametric methods are inadequate. Rather, we attempt a different and perhaps more flexible methodology, and compare its results to the standard regression methodology Findings.The equity ratio variable represents expectation that given the firm size, the higher the investments of stockholders (equity), the higher their return (net income). Finally, the CEO and top management compensation variables are controlling for the managers’ input.One of our central points is that top managers’ actions and skills affect firm output. Hence, higher pay mangers (who presumably are also higher-skill) are expected to yield superior profits. Rosen (1982) relates executives’ pay and rank in the organization to their skills and abilities, and Murphy (1998) discusses in detail th e structure of executive pay and its relation to firm’s performance.The DEA analysis and the empirical estimation of the relative performance of different organizational forms are repeated in four separate subsets of firms:Investment companies, Industrial companies, Real-estate companies, and Trade and services companies. This sector analysis controls for the special business environment of the firms and facilitates further examination of the net effect of ownership structure on firm performance.5.Empirical ResultsThe main results of the empirical findings reviewed above are that majority Control by a few individuals diminishes firm performance, and that professional non-owner managers promote performance. The conclusions about individual control and professional management are reinforced by two other findings. First, it appears that firms without professional managers and firms controlled by individuals are more likely to exhibit negative net income.Second, Table IV also presents results of regressions of net income, NET INC, on leverage, size, professional manager dummy, and individual control dummy.6. ConclusionsThe empirical analysis of 280 firms in Israel reveals that ownership structure impacts firm performance, where performance is estimated as the actual net income of the firm divided by the optimal net income given the firm’s inputs. We find that:(1)Out of all organizational forms, family owner-managed firms appear least efficient in generating profits. When all firms are considered, only family firms with owner managers have an average performance score of less than 30%, and when performance is measured relative to the business sector, only family firms with owner-managers have an average score of less than 50%.(2)Non-owner managed firms perform better than owner-managed firms. These findings suggest that the modern form of business organization, namely the open corporation with disperse ownership and non-owner managers, promotes performance.Critical readers may wonder how come “efficient” and “less-efficient” organizational structures coexist. The answer is that we probably do not document a long-term equilibrium situation. The lower-performing family (and partnership controlled) firms are likely, as time progresses, to transform into public-controlled non-majority owned corporations.A few reservations are in order. First, we do not contend that every company would gain by transforming into a disperse ownership public firm. For example, it is clear that start-up companies are usually better off when they are closely held. Second, there remain questions about the methodology and its application (Data EnvelopmentAnalysis is not standard in Finance). Last, we did not show directly that transforming into a disperse ownership public firm improves performances. Future research should further explore any performance gains from the separation of ownership and control.译文股权结构与公司业绩资料来源:管理治理杂志作者:贝尼·劳特巴赫和亚历山大·范尼斯基多年来,在许多经济体中的大多数商业活动是由独资企业、合伙企业或者非公开企业操作管理的。