尼克尔森中级微观经济学第九版答案ch13
- 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
- 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
- 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。
CHAPTER 13
MONOPOLY
The problems in this chapter deal primarily with marginal revenue-marginal cost calculations in different contexts. For such problems, students’ primary difficulty is to remember that the marginal revenue concept requires differentiation with respect to quantity. Often students choose to differentiate total revenue with respect to price and then get very confused on how to set this equal to marginal cost. Of course, it is possible to phrase the monopolist’s problem as one of choosing a profit-maximizing price, but then the inverse demand function must be used to derive a marginal cost expression. The other principal focus of some of the problems in this chapter is consumer’s surplus. Because the computations usually involve linear deman d curves, they are quite straightforward.
Comments on Problems
13.1 A simple marginal revenue–marginal cost and consumer surplus computation.
13.2 An example of the MR = MC calculation with three different types of cost curves.
13.3 An example of the MR = MC calculation with three different demand and marginal
revenue curves. Illustrates the “inverse elasticity” rule.
13.4 Examines graphically the various possible ways in which shift in demand may affect the
market equilibrium in a monopoly.
13.5 Introduces advertising expenditures as a choice variable for a monopoly. The problem
also asks the student to view market price as the decision variable for the monopoly. 13.6 This problem examines taxation of monopoly output. It shows that some results from
competitive tax-incidence theory do not carry over.
13.7 A price discrimination example in which markets are separated by transport costs. The
problem shows how the price differential is constrained by the extent of those costs. Part
d asks students to consider a simpl
e two-part tariff.
13.8 A marginal revenue-marginal cost computation for the case in which monopolist’s costs
exceed those of a perfect competitor. The problem suggests that the social losses from
such increased costs may be of the same order of magnitude as the deadweight loss from monopolization.
13.9 This problem examines some issues in the design of subsidies for a monopoly.
13.10 A problem involving quality choice. Shows that in this case, monopolist’s and
competitive choices are the same (though output levels differ).
64
Chapter 13/Monopoly 65
65
Solutions
13.1 a. P = 53 – Q PQ = 53Q –Q 2 MR = 53 – 2Q = MC = 5
Q = 24, P = 29, π = (P – AC) ⋅ Q = 576
b. MC = P = 5 P = 5, Q = 48
c. Competitive Consumers' Surplus = 2(48)2 = 1152.
Under monopoly:
Notice that the sum of consumer surplus, profits, and deadweight loss under monopoly equals competitive consumer surplus.
13.2 Market demand Q = 70 –P , MR = 70 –2Q . a. AC = MC = 6. To maximize profits set MC = MR. 6 = 70 – 2Q Q = 32 P = 38
π = (P – AC) ⋅ Q = (38 –6) 32 = 1024
b. C = .25Q 2 – 5Q + 300, MC = .5Q – 5. Set MC = MR .5Q – 5 = 70 – 2Q Q = 30 P = 40 π = TR – TC = (30)(40) – [.25(30)2 –5 (30) + 300] = 825.
c. C = .0133Q 3 – 5Q + 250. MC = .04Q 2 – 5
MC = MR
Therefore: 04Q 2 – 5 = 70 –2Q or .04Q 2 + 2Q – 75=0.
Quadratic formula gives Q = 25. If Q = 25, P = 45 R = 1125
C = 332.8 (MC = 20) π = 792.2