金融学 外文文献 英文文献 外文翻译 担保的作用和个人担保贷款的关系
- 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
- 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
- 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。
金融学外文文献英文文献外文翻译担保的作用和个人
担保贷款的关系
外文文献原文
Material Source: Hitotsubashi University Author: lichiro uesugi
Role of collateral and personal guarantees in relationship lending: evidence
from Japan's SME loan market
1 Introduction
A key issue of interest in the recent literature on financial intermediation has been the role of relationship lending. Relationship lending is particularly common in the case of small business lending, because small businesses typically rely on bank loans for a substantial part of their financing needs but also tend to be informationally opaque. An important issue in this context is the use of collateral, which is a common feature of loan contracts between small firms and banks around
the world, and a number of theoretical and empirical studies have examined why it is so widespread and how it relates to the incentives
for borrowers and lenders and the borrower-lender relationship. For instance, it has been argued that in the presence of information asymmetries between creditors and borrowers, collateral may mitigate the problem of adverse selection (Bester, 1985; 1987) and/or the problem of moral hazard (Bester, 1994; Boot, Thakor, and Udell, 1991). Collateral also affects the incentives of creditors, who will use it either as a
substitute for (Manove, Padilla, and Pagano, 2001) or complement to (Rajan and Winton, 1995; Boot 2000; Longhofer and Santos, 2000) screening and monitoring efforts. Another aspect of collateral that studies have concentrated on is that its presence may depend on the length and intimacy of the relationship between creditors and borrowers (Boot, 2000; Boot and Thakor, 1994; Sharpe, 1990). Existing empirical research has yet to reach decisive conclusions about the nature of these relationships.
This paper seeks to contribute to the existing literature on collateral using a unique firm-level data set of the small and medium sized enterprise (SME) loan market in Japan. Explicitly differentiating physical collateral (such as real estate) and personal guarantees by business representatives, we investigate how the use of collateral and personal guarantees affects the incentives of borrowers, lenders, and the relationship between them. More specifically, we examine the following three issues. First, we examine whether riskier borrowers are more likely to be required to provide collateral or personal guarantees. Second, we investigate how collateral and personal guarantees affect banks’ monitoring of borrowers. Third, we examine the
1
correlation between the use of collateral and personal guarantees on the one hand and the closeness of borrower-lender relationships on the other.
The data set we employ is based mainly on the “Survey of the Financial Environment” (SFE) conducted by the Small and Medium Enterprise Agency of Japan in October 2002. In order to focus on firms that mostly depend on bank loans for their financing, we limit the sample to firms satisfying the legal definition of an SME in Japan. We then combine the SFE data for each SME with information on their main bank obtained from the bank’s financial
statements in order to control for lender characteristics as well. Furthermore, to control for the effect of government credit guarantees on collateral and personal guarantees, in the main analysis of this paper we exclude from the sample all firms that enjoyed any form of government credit guarantee.
As a result of this screening process, we end up with a sample of 1,702 firms. Our main findings can be summarized as follows. We find that firms’ riskiness does not have a significant effect on the likelihood that collateral is used. Thus, we cannot find firm evidence that the use of collateral mitigates moral hazard. We find, however, that banks whose claims are collateralized monitor borrowers more intensively, and that borrowers who have a long-term relationship with their main bank are more likely to pledge collateral. These findings suggest that collateral is complementary to relationship lending. In contrast, the complementarity between relationship lending and personal guarantees is weaker.
As far as we know, this is the first empirical study that systematically examines the role of collateral and personal guarantees
in Japan’s SME loan market. The two main contributions of the paper are as follows. First, given that Japan is generally considered to have a relationship-based financial system in which the relationship-lender, the main bank, plays a central role in corporate financing (Rajan and Zingales, 2003), the study helps to improve our understanding of the
role of collateral in relationship lending and complements existing studies that focus on the United States and Europe. Second, and more importantly, by distinguishing collateral and personal guarantees, the study detects an important role of collateral in relationship lending that has not been remarked on much before. As we argue below, although a typical SME in Japan has a long-term relationship with its main bank, it actually engages in transactions with several banks, which is not common in other countries. A possible corollary of this is that because of the informational
2
free-rider problem it creates, this practice may reduce the main bank’s incentive to screen and monitor borrowers. Since collateral defines the order of seniority among creditors, using collateral may mitigate the free-rider problem and enhance the main bank’s screening and monitoring. This incentive effect for the main bank becomes tenuous for personal guarantees, because personal guarantees do not define the seniority among creditors. Thus, our work provides empirical evidence on
how collateral affects relationship lenders’ incentives, and complements previous studies that focus on the problem of borrower incentives (moral hazard and adverse selection).
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 develops our empirical hypotheses which are based on previous
theoretical models and empirical research. Section 3 describes the data and variables that are used in the paper, and explains our empirical model.
Section 4 presents the results of our empirical analysis, and
Section 5 concludes.
2 Empirical hypotheses
2.1 Borrower riskiness
Much of the empirical literature in this field examines theoretical predictions of asymmetric information models on the relationship between risk and collateral. If the bank cannot discern borrowers’ riskiness (hidden information), then collateral may serve as a screening device to distinguish between borrowers and to mitigate the adverse selection problem (Bester, 1985). This follows from the observation that a lower-risk borrower has a greater incentive to pledge collateral than a risky borrower, because of his lower probability of failure and loss of collateral. Hence, the lower-risk borrower will choose the contract with collateral.
On the other hand, if the lender can observe the ex-ante risk, but there are information asymmetries with regard to actions taken by the
borrower after the loan is extended, collateral potentially provides an incentive to mitigate moral hazard. Thus, opposite to models focusing on hidden information, those concentrating on hidden action suggest that it is observably riskier borrowers that will pledge collateral, because collateral induces more effort by the borrower (Boot, Thakor, and Udell, 1991), or reduces the incentives of strategic default (Bester, 1994).
Because our data base only contains measures of firms’ observed riskiness
3
(namely, credit scores), we couch our first empirical hypothesis as follows:
Hypothesis 1 (H1): The use of collateral is higher among observably higher-risk (low credit score) borrowers if the lender requires collateral in order to mitigate the extent of moral hazard.
Alternatively, if borrowers pledge collateral as a signal of their unobserved high credit quality, then there is negative or no
relationship between the use of collateral and the credit score.
Consistent with the theory of moral hazard, most existing empirical studies, including Berger and Udell (1990; 1995), have found a positive relationship between colla teral and borrowers’ ex-ante risk. Jiménez, Salas and Saurina (2006)
directly test the adverse selection and moral hazard hypotheses by separating ex-ante and ex-post measures of borrower riskiness, namely defaults prior to and after the loan origination. Their results suggest
that although observed riskiness increases the likelihood that
collateral is used, there is also a negative association between collateral and default after the loan has been granted, which is consistent with the adverse selection argument.
It should be noted that theories of collateral as a solution to
moral hazard and/or adverse selection problems assume collateral is external to the firm.
Unfortunately, our measure of the incidence of collateral does not distinguish between firm (inside) collateral and personal (outside) collateral. Hence, throughout our analysis, we will assume that
collateral is mostly inside, but allow for the fact that there may also be some outside collateral. As for personal guarantees, they clearly represent outside collateral.
2.2 Screening and monitoring by the lender
Recent research on collateral also discusses how collateral affects lenders’ incentives with regard to information production, that is, the screening of borrowers’
quality and the monitoring of their performance. These theories of
the effect of collateral on lenders’ incentives apply to both inside
and outside collateral. Manove, Padilla, and Pagano (2001), for instance, argue that, from banks’ point of view, collateral can be considered as
a substitute for the evaluation of the actual risk of a borrower. Thus, banks that are highly protected by collateral may perform less screening of the projects they finance than is socially optimal.
However, several theoretical studies argue that collateral may complement lenders’ screening and monitoring activities. In the presence of other claimants,
4
lenders’ incentive to monitor borrowers is reduced due to the informational free-rider problem. In order to enhance lenders’
incentive to monitor, loan
contracts must be structured in a way that makes lenders’ payoff sensitive to borrowers’ financial health. Rajan and Winton (1995) argue that collateral may serve as a contractual device to increase lenders’ monitoring incentive, because
collateral is likely to be effective only if its value can be monitored. Moreover, the use of collateral as an incentive will be more extensive when the value of such collateral (as in the case of accounts receivable and inventories, for example) depreciates rapidly if business conditions deteriorate, than when the value of collateral is relatively stable (as in the case of, e.g., real estate). Longhofer and Santos (2000) argue that collateral serves as an incentive for information production by the principal lender in the presence of several creditors, because taking collateral is effective in making its loan senior to
other creditors’ claims. Thus, the bank that provides collateralized loan is able to reap the benefits of screening and monitoring activities. Note that this argument does not straightforwardly apply to personal
guarantees, because, in general, personal guarantees do not define seniority among several creditors.
As we have a proxy variable for the intensity of monitoring by the principal lender, our second hypothesis for the empirical analysis is as follows:
Hypothesis 2 (H2): The use of collateral decreases with the
intensity of monitoring by the principal lender if collateral reduces lenders’ incentive to exert effort in loan management. Alternatively,
if collateral serves as an incentive device to induce monitoring efforts by the principal lender in the presence of other claimants, then we expect a positive relationship between the use of collateral and monitoring intensity. To our knowledge, there are only two existing studies that
empirically assess whether the use of collateral and personal guarantees substitute for or complement screening and monitoring by the lender. Examining Spanish loan data, Jiménez, Salas and Saurina (2006) found that banks with a lower level of expertise (smaller banks and savings banks) in small business lending use collateral more intensively. This is consistent with the theory that collateral is used as a
substitute for the evaluation of credit risk. The present study complements these works investigating the relationship between
collateral and screening by focusing on the relationship between collateral and monitoring using Japanese firm data. Our proxy variable
for monitoring intensity is the frequency of document submissions to
5
the main bank.
2.3 Relationship between the borrower and the lender
The existing literature on relationship lending provides conflicting predictions on how the strength of the relationship between borrower and lender affects the likelihood of collateral being pledged. By establishing a solid relationship with the borrower, the lender learns about the hidden attributes and actions of the borrower, thus reducing information asymmetries. Hence, the terms of loan contracts may become more favorable to the borrower if the firm has transactions with a specific relationship lender over a long period of time and thus establishes trust, resulting in a lower likelihood of collateral being pledged (Boot and Thakor, 1994). However, a solid relationship may become detrimental to the borrower if the bank exerts its information monopoly by charging higher interest rates or requiring more collateral (Sharpe, 1990). If such a hold-up problem is indeed common, then there is likely to be a positive correlation between the strength of a relationship and the use of collateral. It should be noted that these theories assume that the collateral is outside collateral. In addition, collateral can also be used as an incentive device in mitigating the
soft-budget constraint problem in relationship lending (Boot, 2000). For example, consider the case where a borrower in difficulty asks the bank for more credit and reduced interest obligations in order to avoid default. Although a transaction-based lender would not lend to such a
borrower, a relationship lender that has already made loans might accept the borrower’s request in the hope of recovering a previous loan. However, once the borrower realizes he can renegotiate the loan contract relatively easily, he has an incentive to misbehave ex ante (the soft budget problem). In such cases, collateral will increase the ex-post bargaining power of the lender and hence reduce the extent of the soft-budget constraint problem, because collateral makes the value of the lender’s claim less
sensitive to the borrower’s total net worth. These theoretical considerations apply to inside collateral as well as outside collateral and lead to the following hypothesis:
Hypothesis 3 (H3): Borrowers that establish a solid relationship
with their principal lender are less likely to use collateral if the relationship reduces information asymmetries and enhances mutual trust between the borrower and the lender. Alternatively, borrowers with a strong relationship with their principal lender are more likely to use collateral if the effects of the hold-up problem or the mitigation of the soft-budget constraint problem dominate.
6
外文文献译文
资料来源: 日本一桥大学作者:lichiro uesugi
担保的作用和个人担保贷款的关系:
来自日本的中小企业贷款市场的证据
在中小企业的贷款中关系贷款非常的普遍,小企业的贷款主要是依靠银行融资,但是小企业却存在财务不透明的问题。
这篇文章将以日本贷款市场上中小企业的厂商数据试图说明抵押贷款的一些问题。
我们将从以下这三个方面来说明,第一,风险偏好借款者是喜欢抵押贷款还是个人担保贷款。
第二,我们将会调查研究抵押贷款和个人担保贷款如何影响商业银行的监控。
第三,我们一方面将会检查抵押和个人担保物的使用情况,另一方面也会检查债权债务人的关系。
为了将注意力放到以银行贷款为主要融资方式的中小企业,为了使本文引用的例子更合适于中小企业的定义,我们挑选了一些在日本调查的符合定义的例子。
经过对1702家公司的调研,我们发现抵押品的使用对公司的风险没有重要影响。
因此,我们找不到证据能说明公司抵押品的使用能缓解道德风险。
同时我们也发现声称抵押贷款能使监管更有力的银行和跟某个主要银行有长期借贷关系的借款者更倾向于通过抵押进行担保融资。
这些研究发现说明了抵押贷款与关系借款是互补的。
相反,抵押贷款与个人担保的互补性变的很弱。
据我们所知,这是首次在日本的市场上说明抵押贷款与个人担保的角色。
这篇文章主要有两个贡献,首先,日本是一个考虑以关系为基础而设立的贷款制度的国家,在这个制度里关系借款人和主要的银行在融资中都扮演了一个重要的核心作用。
这篇研究帮助我们理解了抵押贷款在关系融资中的角色。
其次,通过区别抵押和个人担保,研究发现了以前没有被提及过的抵押品在关系贷款中的重要角色。
在日本,尽管一个典型的中小企业和一家银行保持了长期的合作关系,但实际上他也和其他的好几家银行进行交易,这在其他国家是不常见的。
一个可能的推想是由于它创造的信息免费搭车问题,这个惯例可能会激励主要银行减少对该企业的监控和监督。
银行会根据抵押品来给借款人划分信用等级。
使用抵押品可能会减少搭便车问题,从而加强主要银行对借款银行的检查与监测。
这种激励制度对主要银行的个人担保效果开始慢慢减弱,因为它没有定义债权人的资
历。
因此,我们的工作提供了关于如何影响抵押贷款的激励机制实证,并补充了以前的研究,侧重于借款人激励问题。
在这块领域的大部分文学经验者提出了关于抵押品与风险之间的信息不对称的理论预测模型。
如果银行不能快速的辨认出借款人的风险程度,则抵押品可作为一种筛选设备来区别借款人的信用等级同时也减轻了逆向选择问题,这是从观察一个低风险的借款人为何有更大的动力去抵押贷款而得出的,因为他
7
有较低的贷款抵押损失的可能性,而一个高风险的借款人是不会偏向抵押贷款的。
因此,一个低风险的贷款人会选择抵押贷款合同。
另一方面,如果贷款人能察觉到事前的风险(但这里也有当借款人获得贷款延期后行为上与信息的不对称),贷款有可能是在鼓励减少道德风险。
因此,与模型相反的是我们应该将注意放在隐藏的风险上,这些隐藏的风险表明高风险的借款人的抵押担保物是能够诱使贷款人的或者这些抵押物已经被处理过从而减少了能被发现的缺点。
对抵押品的最新研究还讨论了如何影响抵押贷款的激励机制与生产方面的信息,即借款人的素质筛选和他们的业绩的监测。
在对贷款人的激励机制的附带影响的理论里,同样适用于内部和外部的抵押品。
Manove, Padilla, and Pagano (2001),站在银行的角度认为抵押品可以看作是对借款人的实际风险评估的替代品。
因此,银行对抵押品的高度保护可以对该项目执行较少的筛选。
然而,一些理论研究认为,抵押贷款品可以补充机构的检查和监测活动。
其他人声称由于信息搭便车的问题减少了贷款人对借款人的监督。
而我们对第二种假设的实证认为,如果抵押品作为一种激励手段,具有促使贷款人监督的效果,则我们期待它能在担保和使用监测力度方面也有积极的效应。
通过建立一个与借款人稳固的关系,贷款人就会学到更多的隐藏属性和借款人的行动,因此而减少信息的不对称。
因此,他的贷款合同条款可能会更受借款人喜
欢,如果企业与贷款人有一个特定的长时间的交易关系,则可能因此而建立起了信任,而可能会得到比较低的抵押品的贷款。
信贷贷款的使用大大减少了银行对于抵押和个人担保的激励机制。
为了绕过这个问题,我们排除了那些享受无论何种形式的政府保证的中小企业样本。
这样做有三方面优势,首先,SFE询问是否有借款公司向关系银行抵押贷款。
其次,除了抵押和个人担保外,SFE在借款者和他的关系银行中问了一个详细丰富的关于融资转换的问题。
这些都使我们更清楚的知道抵押时如何和关系银行的监管联系起来的。
最后,通过SFE的数据和中小企业、银行的数据配对联系,我们能够控制借款企业和主要银行对其提供抵押贷款的特点。
我们发现企业的风险对贷款的使用可能性并没有重大效果。
我们发现关系银行声称用抵押物监测借款者更有效,借款者与某银行长期合作关系则更倾向于抵押贷款。
我们的经验证据表明,抵押与关系贷款时相辅相成的。
相反,个人担保与关系贷款的相辅作用是很弱的。
日本的中小企业与其他的国家不一样,他们更喜欢选择多家银行进行融资。
对主要银行的激励和监督借款人,建立稳固的合作关系可能会减少由于信息搭便车问题。
8。