清华大学中级微观经济学讲义(清华 李稻葵)24
合集下载
相关主题
- 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
- 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
- 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。
http://www.sem.tsinghua.edu.cn/ Chapter Twenty-Four Monopoly
What do we do in this chapter
We studied the case of pure competition, in which case, each firm is very small; We now study the other extreme: There is a single firm.
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
A quantity tax of $t/output unit raises the marginal cost of production by $t. The quantity tax is distortionary. See the following figure.
t
The amount of the tax paid by buyers is t
p(y ) − p(y*).
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
(k + t)ε kε tε p(y ) − p(y*) = − = 1+ ε 1+ ε 1+ ε
t
Because ε < -1, ε /(1+ε) > 1 and so the monopolist passes on to consumers more than the tax!
Marginal Revenue
E.g. if p(y) = a - by then R(y) = p(y)y = ay - by2 and so MR(y) = a - 2by < a - by = p(y) for y > 0. a p(y) = a - by
a/2b
a/b y MR(y) = a - 2by
$
Marginal Cost
c(y) = F + αy + βy2
F $/output unit y MC(y) = α + 2βy β α y
Profit-Maximization; An Example
$/output unit a
p(y*) = a−b a−α 2(b + β)
p(y) = a - by MC(y) = α + 2βy β
so, for y = y*,
d dc(y) . (p(y)y) = dy dy
Profit-Maximization
$
R(y) = p(y)y
y
Profit-Maximization
$
R(y) = p(y)y c(y)
y
Profit-Maximization
$
R(y) = p(y)y c(y)
Markup Pricing
1 + 1 = k ⇒ p(y*) = k = kε p(y*) 1 1+ ε ε 1+ ε
is the monopolist’s price. The markup is
kε k p(y*) − k = . −k = − 1+ ε 1+ ε
The markup rises as the own-price elasticity of demand rises towards -1.
y*
y Π(y)
Profit-Maximization
$
R(y) = p(y)y c(y)
y*
y Π(y)
Profit-Maximization
$
R(y) = p(y)y c(y)
y*
At the profit-maximizing output level the slopes of the revenue and total cost Π(y) curves are equal; MR(y*) = MC(y*).
A Profits Tax Levied on a Monopoly
A profits tax levied at rate t reduces profit from Π(y*) to (1-t)Π(y*). Π What is the impact of t on y*? Zero impact! I.e., the profits tax is a neutral tax.
yt y* MR(y)
y
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
$/output unit p(y) p(yt) p(y*) The quantity tax causes a drop in the output level, a rise in the output’s price and a decline in demand for inputs. MC(y) + t t MC(y)
Pure Monopoly
$/output unit p(y)
Higher output y causes a lower market price, p(y).
Output Level, y
Pure Monopoly
Suppose that the monopolist seeks to maximize its economic profit,
yt y* MR(y)
y
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
Can a monopolist “pass” all of a $t quantity tax to the consumers? Suppose the marginal cost of production is constant at $k/output unit. With no tax, the monopolist’s price is
kε p(y*) = . 1+ ε
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
The tax increases marginal cost to $(k+t)/output unit, changing the profit-maximizing price to
(k + t)ε p(y ) = . 1+ ε
α源自文库
y* = a−α 2(b + β)
y MR(y) = a - 2by
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand
Suppose that market demand becomes less sensitive to changes in price (i.e. the own-price elasticity of demand becomes less negative).
p(y) dy 1 + 1. ε= so MR(y) = p(y) ε y dp(y)
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand
1 + 1. MR(y) = p(y) ε
Suppose the monopolist’s marginal cost of production is constant, at $k/output unit. For a profit-maximum 1 + 1 = k MR(y*) = p(y*) which is k ε p(y*) = . 1 1+ ε
Markup Pricing
Markup pricing: Output price is the marginal cost of production plus a “markup.” How big is a monopolist’s markup and how does it change with the own-price elasticity of demand?
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand d dp(y) MR(y) = (p(y)y) = p(y) + y dy dy
y dp(y) = p(y)1 + . p(y) dy
Own-price elasticity of demand is
Marginal Cost
Marginal cost is the rate-of-change of total cost as the output level y increases; dc(y) MC(y) = . dy E.g. if c(y) = F + αy + βy2 then
MC(y) = α + 2βy.
Π(y) = p(y)y − c(y).
What output level y* maximizes profit?
Profit-Maximization
Π(y) = p(y)y − c(y).
At the profit-maximizing output level y*
dΠ(y) d dc(y) = =0 (p(y)y) − dy dy dy
Pure Monopoly
A monopolized market has a single seller. The monopolist’s demand curve is the (downward sloping) market demand curve. So the monopolist can alter the market price by adjusting its output level.
The Inefficiency of Monopoly
A market is Pareto efficient if it achieves the maximum possible total gains-to-trade. Otherwise a market is Pareto inefficient.
y
Marginal Revenue
Marginal revenue is the rate-of-change of revenue as the output level y increases; d dp(y) MR(y) = (p(y)y) = p(y) + y . dy dy dp(y)/dy is the slope of the market inverse demand function so dp(y)/dy < 0. Therefore dp(y) MR(y) = p(y) + y < p(y) dy for y > 0.
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand
1 + 1 = k, Notice that, since MR(y*) = p(y*) ε 1 + 1 > 0 ⇒ 1 + 1 > 0 p(y*) ε ε 1 > −1 ⇒ ε < −1. That is, ε So a profit-maximizing monopolist always selects an output level for which market demand is own-price elastic.
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
$/output unit p(y) p(y*) MC(y)
y* MR(y)
y
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
$/output unit p(y) p(yt) p(y*) MC(y) + t t MC(y)
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand
p(y*) = k 1 1+ ε .
So as ε rises towards -1 the monopolist alters its output level to make the market price of its product to rise.
What do we do in this chapter
We studied the case of pure competition, in which case, each firm is very small; We now study the other extreme: There is a single firm.
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
A quantity tax of $t/output unit raises the marginal cost of production by $t. The quantity tax is distortionary. See the following figure.
t
The amount of the tax paid by buyers is t
p(y ) − p(y*).
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
(k + t)ε kε tε p(y ) − p(y*) = − = 1+ ε 1+ ε 1+ ε
t
Because ε < -1, ε /(1+ε) > 1 and so the monopolist passes on to consumers more than the tax!
Marginal Revenue
E.g. if p(y) = a - by then R(y) = p(y)y = ay - by2 and so MR(y) = a - 2by < a - by = p(y) for y > 0. a p(y) = a - by
a/2b
a/b y MR(y) = a - 2by
$
Marginal Cost
c(y) = F + αy + βy2
F $/output unit y MC(y) = α + 2βy β α y
Profit-Maximization; An Example
$/output unit a
p(y*) = a−b a−α 2(b + β)
p(y) = a - by MC(y) = α + 2βy β
so, for y = y*,
d dc(y) . (p(y)y) = dy dy
Profit-Maximization
$
R(y) = p(y)y
y
Profit-Maximization
$
R(y) = p(y)y c(y)
y
Profit-Maximization
$
R(y) = p(y)y c(y)
Markup Pricing
1 + 1 = k ⇒ p(y*) = k = kε p(y*) 1 1+ ε ε 1+ ε
is the monopolist’s price. The markup is
kε k p(y*) − k = . −k = − 1+ ε 1+ ε
The markup rises as the own-price elasticity of demand rises towards -1.
y*
y Π(y)
Profit-Maximization
$
R(y) = p(y)y c(y)
y*
y Π(y)
Profit-Maximization
$
R(y) = p(y)y c(y)
y*
At the profit-maximizing output level the slopes of the revenue and total cost Π(y) curves are equal; MR(y*) = MC(y*).
A Profits Tax Levied on a Monopoly
A profits tax levied at rate t reduces profit from Π(y*) to (1-t)Π(y*). Π What is the impact of t on y*? Zero impact! I.e., the profits tax is a neutral tax.
yt y* MR(y)
y
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
$/output unit p(y) p(yt) p(y*) The quantity tax causes a drop in the output level, a rise in the output’s price and a decline in demand for inputs. MC(y) + t t MC(y)
Pure Monopoly
$/output unit p(y)
Higher output y causes a lower market price, p(y).
Output Level, y
Pure Monopoly
Suppose that the monopolist seeks to maximize its economic profit,
yt y* MR(y)
y
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
Can a monopolist “pass” all of a $t quantity tax to the consumers? Suppose the marginal cost of production is constant at $k/output unit. With no tax, the monopolist’s price is
kε p(y*) = . 1+ ε
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
The tax increases marginal cost to $(k+t)/output unit, changing the profit-maximizing price to
(k + t)ε p(y ) = . 1+ ε
α源自文库
y* = a−α 2(b + β)
y MR(y) = a - 2by
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand
Suppose that market demand becomes less sensitive to changes in price (i.e. the own-price elasticity of demand becomes less negative).
p(y) dy 1 + 1. ε= so MR(y) = p(y) ε y dp(y)
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand
1 + 1. MR(y) = p(y) ε
Suppose the monopolist’s marginal cost of production is constant, at $k/output unit. For a profit-maximum 1 + 1 = k MR(y*) = p(y*) which is k ε p(y*) = . 1 1+ ε
Markup Pricing
Markup pricing: Output price is the marginal cost of production plus a “markup.” How big is a monopolist’s markup and how does it change with the own-price elasticity of demand?
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand d dp(y) MR(y) = (p(y)y) = p(y) + y dy dy
y dp(y) = p(y)1 + . p(y) dy
Own-price elasticity of demand is
Marginal Cost
Marginal cost is the rate-of-change of total cost as the output level y increases; dc(y) MC(y) = . dy E.g. if c(y) = F + αy + βy2 then
MC(y) = α + 2βy.
Π(y) = p(y)y − c(y).
What output level y* maximizes profit?
Profit-Maximization
Π(y) = p(y)y − c(y).
At the profit-maximizing output level y*
dΠ(y) d dc(y) = =0 (p(y)y) − dy dy dy
Pure Monopoly
A monopolized market has a single seller. The monopolist’s demand curve is the (downward sloping) market demand curve. So the monopolist can alter the market price by adjusting its output level.
The Inefficiency of Monopoly
A market is Pareto efficient if it achieves the maximum possible total gains-to-trade. Otherwise a market is Pareto inefficient.
y
Marginal Revenue
Marginal revenue is the rate-of-change of revenue as the output level y increases; d dp(y) MR(y) = (p(y)y) = p(y) + y . dy dy dp(y)/dy is the slope of the market inverse demand function so dp(y)/dy < 0. Therefore dp(y) MR(y) = p(y) + y < p(y) dy for y > 0.
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand
1 + 1 = k, Notice that, since MR(y*) = p(y*) ε 1 + 1 > 0 ⇒ 1 + 1 > 0 p(y*) ε ε 1 > −1 ⇒ ε < −1. That is, ε So a profit-maximizing monopolist always selects an output level for which market demand is own-price elastic.
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
$/output unit p(y) p(y*) MC(y)
y* MR(y)
y
Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist
$/output unit p(y) p(yt) p(y*) MC(y) + t t MC(y)
Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand
p(y*) = k 1 1+ ε .
So as ε rises towards -1 the monopolist alters its output level to make the market price of its product to rise.