行为金融学的综述--Behavioral Corporate Finance: A Survey -- Baker Ruback Wurgler

合集下载

财务市场的行为金融学

财务市场的行为金融学

财务市场的行为金融学财务市场的行为金融学(Behavioral finance)是金融市场中的一个分支学科,它研究人们在金融决策中的行为模式和心理机制。

行为金融学认为,市场不是完全理性的,投资者也不是理性的,他们在决策过程中会受到各种影响因素的制约,从而导致市场波动和投资回报的不确定性。

在这篇文章中,我们将探讨财务市场中的行为金融学,了解其理论基础、实际应用和未来发展趋势。

一、理论基础行为金融学的理论基础主要来自于心理学、博弈论和社会学等学科。

心理学方面,行为金融学主要研究投资者的认知偏差、情绪反应、判断失误和决策行为。

博弈论方面,行为金融学主要研究投资者的对决策者的期望和行动的反应。

社会学方面,行为金融学主要研究投资者的信任、规范和价值观。

行为金融学认为,人们在金融决策中会受到多种认知偏差的影响,如选择偏差、确认偏差、过度自信和亏损厌恶等。

人们在面对风险时,也会受到情绪反应的影响,如恐惧、贪婪和厌恶等。

此外,人们在决策时还会受到群体效应、遵循效应和信息不对称等因素的影响。

二、实际应用行为金融学的实际应用主要涵盖三个方面:金融产品设计、投资决策辅助和市场规制。

金融产品设计方面,行为金融学可以为金融机构提供有关产品设计和销售策略的建议,以帮助客户更好地理解和选择金融产品。

投资决策辅助方面,行为金融学可以为投资者提供行为金融咨询和风险管理建议,以帮助他们做出更明智的投资决策。

市场规制方面,行为金融学可以为金融监管机构提供政策建议,以更好地保护投资者的权益和维护市场秩序。

以资产定价为例,行为金融学认为,投资者的做法是非理性的,由于投资者在信息充分而基础论不成立的情况下,进行了高度风险规避的操作,引发了一定的市场波动。

因此,在资产定价方面,行为金融学反对Efficient Market Hypothesis(有效市场假说),认为市场并不是完全理性的,也不是完全有效的,它存在着诸如信息异质性以及交易者非理性行为等因素。

行为金融理论文献综述

行为金融理论文献综述

行为金融理论文献综述行为金融理论文献综述相对于现代金融理论,行为金融学的发展历史并不很长。

从20世纪90年代,学术界开始形成了研究行为金融的热潮,大量的学者投身于行为金融方面的研究。

行为金融定义的讨论行为金融作为一个新兴的研究领城,虽然己经有了20多年的发展历史,但至今还没有一个为学术界所公认的严格定义。

Thaler(1993)认为行为金融就是“思路开放式金融研究”(open-minded 'finance),只要是对现实世界关注,考虑经济系统中的人有可能不是完全理性的,就可以认为是研究行为金融。

Lintner(1998)把行为金融学研究定义为“研先人类如何解释以及根据信息、做出决策”。

Olsen(1998)声称“行为金融学并不是试图去定义‘理性’的行为或者把决策打上偏差或错误的标记;行为金融学是寻求理解并预测进行市场心理决策过程的系统含义”。

Statman(1999)则认为金融学从来就未离开过心理学,一切行为均是基于心理考虑的结果,行为金融学与标准金融学的不同在于对心理、行为的观点有所不同。

Sheinn(2000)认为,行为金融是将行为科学、心理学和认知科学上的成果运用到金融市场中产生的学科,其主要研究方法,是基于心理学实验结果提出投资者决策时的心理特征假设来研究投资者的实际投资决策行为。

Russell (2000)对行为金融是这样定义的:(1)行为金融理论是传统经济学、传统金融理论、心理学研究以及决策科学的综合体。

(2)行为金融理论试图解释实证研究发现的与传统金融理论不一致的异常之处。

(3)行为金融理论研究投资者在做出判断时是怎样出错的,或者说是研究投资者是如何在判断中发生系统性的错误的。

从上述行为金融学家定义的行为金融概念可以得出如下结论,行为金融研究考虑到了人的不完全理性的本性,其研究需要运用行为科学和心理学知识,其研究对象是金融领域的相关现象及其本质。

行为金融的发展历史通常把行为金融的研究历史划分为三个阶段:1.早期行为金融研究。

行为金融学概况

行为金融学概况

行为金融学(Behavioral Finance,简称BF)什么是行为金融学行为金融学是金融学、心理学、行为学、社会学等学科相交叉的边缘学科,力图揭示金融市场的非理性行为和决策规律。

行为金融理论认为,证券的市场价格并不只由证券内在价值所决定,还在很大程度上受到投资者主体行为的影响,即投资者心理与行为对证券市场的价格决定及其变动具有重大影响。

它是和有效市场假说(efficient market hypothesis,EMH)相对应的一种学说,主要内容可分为套利限制(limits of arbitrage)和心理学两部分。

由于是一个新兴的研究领域,行为金融学至今还没有为学术界所公认的严格定义,因而在此只能给出几种由行为金融学领域一些颇有影响的学者所提出的定义。

虽然无法避免其局限性,但各有其独到的见解,可以作为行为金融学研究的基础性概念。

(1)美国芝加哥大学教授Thaler认为,行为金融学是指研究人类理解信息并随之行动,作出投资决策的学科。

通过大量的实验模型,它发现投资者行为并不总是理性、可预测和公正的,实际上,投资者经常会犯错。

(2)美国耶鲁大学教授Shiller认为,行为金融学是从对人们决策时的实际心理特征研究人手讨论投资者决策行为的,其投资决策模型是建立在人们投资决策时的心理因素的假设基础上的(当然这些关于投资者心理因素的假设是建立在心理学实证研究结果基础上的)。

行为金融学的研究思想相对于传统经济学是一种逆向的逻辑。

传统经济学理论是首先创造理想然后逐步走向现实,其关注的重心是在理想状况下应该发生什么;而行为金融学则是以经验的态度关注实际上发生了什么及其深层的原因是什么。

这种逻辑是一种现实的逻辑、发现的逻辑。

从根本上来说,行为金融学所研究的是市场参与者表现出的真实情况是什么样的,以及从市场参与者所表现出的特性来解释一些金融现象。

行为金融学家认为:①投资者是有限理性的,投资者是会犯错误的。

②在绝大多数时候,市场中理性和有限理性的投资者都是起作用的(而非标准金融理论中的非理性投资者最终将被赶出市场,理性投资者最终决定价格)。

行为金融学理论研究及运用

行为金融学理论研究及运用

行为金融学理论研究及运用一、引言在金融学的历史演进中,行为金融学(Behavioral Finance)逐渐发展成为一种重要的研究领域。

它研究人们在金融决策中的心理和行为过程,挑战了传统金融学理论的假设和预测。

行为金融学理论不仅在学术界产生了广泛的影响,也在实践领域,如投资策略、风险管理、市场预测等,展现出巨大的潜力。

二、行为金融学的理论背景行为金融学理论的发展源自于心理学和金融学的交叉研究。

传统金融学理论基于理性人假设,认为投资者在决策过程中能够理性地权衡风险和收益,并做出最优决策。

然而,心理学的研究表明,人们在面对风险和不确定性时,往往受到认知偏差、情绪影响、社会压力等多种心理因素的影响,无法完全理性地做出决策。

行为金融学就是试图解释这些心理因素如何影响金融市场的行为和结果。

三、行为金融学的理论研究行为金融学理论主要两个方面:一是投资者行为,即投资者在金融市场中的决策过程和行为模式;二是市场有效性,即市场价格反映所有可用信息的程度和速度。

在投资者行为方面,行为金融学理论研究了诸如过度自信、代表性启发、可得性启发等心理偏差对投资者决策的影响。

在市场有效性方面,行为金融学挑战了有效市场假说(EMH),提出了诸如过度反应、反应不足等市场异常现象的理论解释。

四、行为金融学的运用行为金融学在实践运用中具有广泛的应用前景。

行为金融学可以用于改善投资者的决策过程。

通过识别和纠正心理偏差,投资者可以更加理性地看待市场波动,减少非理性行为的影响。

行为金融学可以用于设计更有效的投资策略。

例如,基于投资者过度自信的心理特点,可以通过构造具有相对低估价值的投资组合,实现更高的投资回报。

行为金融学还可以用于监管和市场设计。

例如,通过了解市场参与者的心理和行为特点,可以制定更有效的监管政策和市场规则。

五、结论行为金融学理论研究及运用展示了金融学与心理学的深度融合,以及这种融合在改善金融决策和提高金融市场效率方面的巨大潜力。

行为金融学

行为金融学

• 损失厌恶(loss aversion)是指人们面对同 样的损失和收益时感到损失对情绪影响更 大。与此相关联的是禀赋效应 (endowment effect),它反映了将现状作 为参考点,损失比收益更难让人忍受,所 以决策者偏爱现状。同时Benartzi and Thaler(1995)提出“短视的损失厌恶” (myopic loss aversion),认为长期收益 可能被周期性的短期损失打断,引出了投 资者认为的“赌场论”。
行为金融学理论
• Shefrin(2000)则在《Beyond Greed and Fear》一书中,将行为金融学的研究领域 分为三部分,即启发式偏差(heuristicdriven bias)、框定依赖(framing dependence)和无效率市场(inefficient markets )。
情绪过程
• 后悔厌恶(regret aversion),指人们做出错 误决策时会感到痛苦。Erlich, Guttman等在 1957年发现新买车的人在购买完成后有选 择的避免阅读没有选择的车型广告,而只 关注自己所选车的广告。
意志过程
• 自我控制(self control)是指控制情绪。存在自我控制时, 个人无法依据理性决策。Shefrin and Statman(1984)认为 个人视股利为所得,而年老者倾向于控制自己过度消费, 会买一些发放股利多的股票,因为他们认为用股利做生活 费不会花掉自己的资产。 • 羊群效应(herd behaviors)指在信息不确定时,投资者 的行为常受他人(其他投资者及舆论)影响。Lakonishok、 Shleifer and Vishny(1992)研究表明,美国的小公司股票 交易具有轻微的羊群效应,这可能与小公司的公开信息较 少,使得基金经理无法判断交易策略有关。 Werners(1999)发现美国的共同基金买入的股票更具同期 与滞后收益,从而认为其羊群效应是理性的,加速了新信 息在股价中的反映,有利于稳定市场。counting)。Shefrin and Statman(2000)发展出BPT后,推广单一心理账户(BPT-SA)与多个心理账户(BPT—MA)用于分析现象,解释 了投资者可能在某一个账户做空证券而在另一账户买进相 同的证券。PBT—MA解释了Friedman—Savage之谜:为 何人们买保险的同时买彩票?心理账户将投资者对收益的 “资本账户”与“红利账户”的区分,区别了资本账户损 失与红利账户损失,认为那些觉得停止分红会使其丧失收 入的小股东们实际上忠实的执行了绝不动用资本利得的自 控规则,从而很好的解决了困扰人们的“红利之谜”。

行为金融学综述:理论与应用

行为金融学综述:理论与应用

行为金融学综述:理论与应用A Survey of Behavioral Finance:Theory and application南京农业大学经济与贸易学院金融02班陈希2003.11行为金融学综述:理论与应用陈希经济贸易学院金融系内容提要:近期的实证金融文献综述常常涉及潜在的来自心理学、社会学、人类学的行为原则, 本文简要地介绍了行为金融学。

行为金融学围绕一系列对理性投资者在有效市场追求预期效用最大化的挑战展开研究。

认知心理学和套利限制构成了行为金融的两大根基。

对新为金融研究的迅速升温源于传统理论框架在众多实证中的解释力匮乏。

本文含四部分,一是标准金融理论面临的挑战与行为金融的兴起;二是行为金融学的理论架构;三是行为金融学的现有缺陷及发展前景;四是行为金融学在中国的应用进展及前景。

本文的特色在于:1.对标准金融理论受到挑战的各方面的归纳。

2. 对行为金融学理论架构的独特构造。

3.归纳了行为金融学的不足与前景。

4.较全面地总结了这一新兴领域在中国的研究进展。

关键词:行为金融学非理性心理学市场效率Abstract:Recent literature in empirical finance is surveyed in its relation to underlying behavioral principles, principles which come primarily from psychology, sociology and anthropology.This article provides a brief introduction to behavioral finance. Behavioral finance encompasses research that drops the traditional assumptions of expected utility maximization with rational investors in efficient markets. The two building blocks of behavioral finance are cognitive psychology (how people think) and the limits to arbitrage (when markets will be inefficient).The growth of behavioral finance research has been fueled by the inability of the traditional framework to explain many empirical patterns,This article contains four parts.The first part talks about challenges that modern finance faces and the boon of behavioral finance.The second mainly says about the structure of behavioral finance.The third part is about the bug of the theory behavioral finance and its outlook.The last part deals with its application in China.Key words:Behavioral finance irrationality psychology market efficiency一、标准金融理论面临的挑战与行为金融的兴起Haugen(1999)将金融理论的发展划为三阶段:旧金融学(old finance)、现代金融学(modern finance)以及新金融学(new finance)。

行为金融学综述

行为金融学综述

行为金融学综述08051113 投资2班刘瓅摘要:行为金融学就是将心理学尤其是行为科学的理论融入到金融学之中。

它从微观个体行为以及产生这种行为的心理等动因来解释、研究和预测金融市场的发展。

本文先介绍了行为金融学的起源,再从模型和理论两方面,对行为金融的内容进行综述,最后对发展前景进行了分析。

关键字:行为金融理论模型套利限制行为金融学是一门新兴学科,作为金融学理论研究的新领域,与现代金融理论的理性分析框架相比,它更重视人的实际心理和经济行为,从而为金融决策提供了更为现实的指导方案。

行为金融学在对现代金融理论缺陷的修正中,在行为认知偏差、行为组合理论、期望理论、行为资产定价模型等方面取得了一定的理论研究成果,捉进了金融学理论研究向更现实的方向发展。

行为金融学作为行为经济学的一个分支,于19世纪50年代萌芽。

行为金融理论是将行为理论与金融分析相结合的研究方法和理论体系,它分析人的行为、心理以及情绪对人的金融决策、金融产品的价格以及金融市场发展趋势的影响,是心理学与金融学相结合的研究成果。

在20世纪80年代末,一批心理学发展成果成功引进金融学领域,行为金融学才渐渐受到经济学家的瞩目。

2002年,诺贝尔经济学奖授予给行为经济学家Daniel Kahneman和实验经济学家Vernon L.Smith,从此引起了越来越多的研究者对行为金融理论的极大关注,并在近年来得出了许多非常有价值的研究成果。

一、行为金融学的起源行为金融与标准金融理论大约起源于相同的时期。

1951年,美国商务学教授O.K.Burren发表了《投资战略的实验方法的可能性研究》一文,成为最早提出将心理学和金融学结合研究的学者之一。

1969年Bau-man又发表了《科学的投资分析:科学还是幻想》一文。

这两篇文章都呼吁把心理学和金融研究相结合,认为更传统的行为方法和定量投资模型相结合是有益的。

同年,Slovic从行为的观点发表了一篇关于投资过程的详细研究。

行为金融学理论综述

行为金融学理论综述

行为金融学理论综述许亚芬 唐湘筠(南京大学经济系,江苏 南京 210093)摘要:行为金融学的研究主要集中于金融市场中大量存在的“反常现象”,质疑传统金融学理论认为投资者在金融市场中完全理性假设和有效市场假说。

行为金融学主要有两大理论基石:认知心理学和有限套利。

本文从心理学及相关研究成果——有限理性个体以及群体行为——认知(偏差、非贝叶斯过程)决策、选择偏好(预期理论)和有限套利——非有效市场——资产组合及价格发生机制脉络梳理了行为金融学的理论基础和理论框架。

关键词:行为金融学;预期理论;认知心理学;有限套利行为金融学是近年来崛起的一门新兴学科,是一门利用心理学和其他社会科学的研究工具来解释金融市场现象的学科。

最初萌芽于上个世纪五十年代,早在1951年O.K.Burell教授就发表了《一种可用于投资研究的实验方法》一文,率先提出了用实验来讨论理论的必要性;随后的1967年,Bauman发表了《科学投资分析:是科学还是幻想?》,更加明确地批评了金融学科片面依靠模型的治学态度,并指出金融学与行为学的结合应是今后金融学发展的方向。

1979年心理学家Daniel Kahneman和Amose Tversky发表了题为《预期理论:风险状态下的决策分析》的文章,提出了人类风险决策过程的心理学理论,称为预期理论。

一、行为金融学与传统金融理论的区别和联系⑴关于投资者是否是完全理性①:传统金融理论把投资者设为一个完全意义上的理性人,认为投资者是理性的;而行为金融学理论关于投资者的假定则是非完全理性,即有限理性。

⑵关于有效市场假说②:市场有效假说被认为是传统金融理论的核心之一,它充分地反映了传统金融的研究脉络,而行为金融学理论认为市场并非总是有效的。

⑶关于理性预期均衡:绝大多数资产定价模型都是使用理性预期均衡框架,他们假设交易者不但是个人理性的而且信念也是一致的。

这就要求交易者不但能准确处理新信息,而且收集到有关经济结构足够的信息使得交易者能绘出准确的分布。

cfa 3级 behavioral finance

cfa 3级 behavioral finance

cfa 3级 behavioral financeCFA(Chartered Financial Analyst)三级考试中的“Behavioral Finance”(行为金融学)是一个重要的考试科目,涉及到金融市场中投资者行为和心理因素对投资决策的影响。

在 CFA 三级考试中,“Behavioral Finance”可能会涵盖以下内容:1. 投资者心理和行为偏差:了解常见的投资者心理偏差,如过度自信、羊群行为、损失厌恶等,以及这些偏差如何影响投资决策。

2. 市场效率和异象:探讨市场效率的概念,包括弱式有效市场、半强式有效市场和强式有效市场。

同时,了解一些常见的市场异象,如日历效应、动量效应等。

3. 投资决策和行为策略:分析投资者在做出投资决策时的行为模式,以及如何利用行为金融学的概念来制定更有效的投资策略。

4. 风险感知和管理:了解投资者对风险的感知和态度,以及如何通过行为金融学的方法来管理风险。

5. 团队决策和投资组合管理:探讨团队决策中的行为因素,以及如何在投资组合管理中考虑行为金融学的概念。

要在 CFA 三级考试的“Behavioral Finance”科目中取得好成绩,建议你:1. 系统学习相关知识:阅读官方教材、参考书籍和相关研究论文,深入理解行为金融学的概念和理论。

2. 做题练习:通过做练习题和模拟试题,熟悉考试的题型和要求,提高解题能力。

3. 案例分析和实际应用:将理论知识应用到实际的金融案例中,分析和解释投资者行为和市场现象。

4. 参加培训课程或学习小组:与其他考生一起学习和讨论,可以分享经验和观点,提高学习效果。

5. 关注最新研究和实践:保持对行为金融学领域的最新研究和实践的关注,了解最新发展动态。

通过全面学习和准备,你将能够更好地应对 CFA 三级考试中的“Behavioral Finance”科目,取得优异的成绩。

请注意,以上内容仅供参考,具体考试内容和要求可能会根据 CFA 协会的最新规定而有所变化。

行为金融学理论综述

行为金融学理论综述

行为金融学理论综述行为金融学理论综述:行为、理性与金融经济学似乎与理性、严谨有着与生俱来的紧密关系,长久以来,建立在人类理性基础上的一系列严格的假设成为了主流经济学的基石,并统领了经济学内部的各个学科。

围绕理性人始终追求效用最大化的预设,金融学形成了由资本资产定价模型CAPM、套利定价模型、资产组合理论、期权定价理论组成的抽象的理论框架。

但是,这些理想的模型似乎在越来越多的现实检验中出现问题,1977年,罗尔(Roll)发现,统计数据与模型的冲突显示作为标准金融学基石的CAPM可能是无法验证的。

之后,在20世纪八、九十年代影响学术界的有效市场假说(EMH),也被指出了许多统计异常现象。

同时,标准金融理论的另一个关键概念β系数,显示出其与股票投资收益仅有不明显的联系。

1992年,作为资本资产定价模型的奠基人之一的E·法玛(Eugene Fama)甚至撤回了对CAPM的支持。

这些无疑把现代金融学推到了一个尴尬的境地:经典的、数量经济基础上的严谨体系如果不是错误的,也至少是很不完善的。

金融学面临着一旁是没有严格的统计数据支持的模型、另一旁是没有理论解释的实证数据的局面,在对学科进行审视和反思的过程中,运用心理学、社会学、行为学来研究金融活动当中人们决策行为的“行为金融学”便成为了学界的关注点。

其实,行为金融学的诞生并不是晚近的事情,在主流金融学的兴起、发展过程中,作为社会科学当中重要分支的行为学早已渗入金融学当中,只是一直在边缘位置上若隐若现。

早在1951年,美国奥兰多商业大学的布鲁尔(O.K.Burell)教授就发表了“一种可用于投资研究的实验方法”一文,率先提出了用实验来讨论理论的必要性;随后的1967年,来自俄勒冈大学的巴曼(Bauman)发表了“科学投资分析:是科学还是幻想?”,更加明确地批评了金融学科片面依靠模型的治学态度,并指出金融学与行为学的结合应是今后金融学发展的方向。

追随他们理论的金融学家也陆续有一些研究问世,但都是散见的,没有足以引起人们的重视。

行为金融学论文

行为金融学论文

行为金融学论文行为金融学就是将心理学尤其是行为科学的理论融入到金融学之中,是一门新兴边缘学科。

下文是店铺为大家整理的关于行为金融学论文的范文,希望能对大家有所帮助,欢迎大家阅读参考!行为金融学论文篇1浅谈行为金融学摘要:行为金融学是伴随着金融市场的发展而兴起的一门新的学科,与传统金融学理论一起,两者构成了金融学的理论体系。

先从行为金融学产生的历史背景谈起,指出行为金融学是历史创造出来的。

随后介绍了行为金融学的理论基础和理论体系,并介绍了行为金融学的几个投资策略。

关键词:行为金融学;理论体系;投资策略一、历史背景自20世纪80年代以来,随着金融市场的迅速发展和研究的深入,出现了许多不能被传统金融学所解释的现象,比如,利好兑现现象、传闻效应、小盘股现象、星期五现象、反应过度和羊群效应等。

这些传统金融理论无法合理的给出解释的现象被称为金融市场中的“异象”,金融市场里出现的大量的异象对传统金融理论造成了巨大的冲击,特别是有效市场假说。

因此,人们开始重新审视传统的金融学理论,随之产生了新的理论――行为金融学。

行为金融理论的研究可以追溯到20世纪50年代。

Burrel在1951年发表的《投资研究实验方法的可能性》中主张把心理学和金融学研究结合起来,提议用构建实验室的方法来验证理论的必要性,认为将行为方法和定量投资模型相结合具有重要意义。

1972 年Slovie发表了一篇启发性的论文《人类判断的心理学研究对投资决策的影响》,自此,行为金融学已现雏形。

然而当时认识心理学尚处于形成阶段,行为决策理论也还没发展成熟,传统金融理论又比较完美,所以这一主张并没引起足够重视,甚至将行为金融理论视为异端邪说。

1979 年Kahneman和Tversky提出了对行为金融理论有重大影响的期望理论,该理论是行为金融学的核心内容和代表学说,是行为金融理论研究的奠基理论。

20世纪90年代,Lars Tvede 出版了《金融心理学》,并创办了《金融分析家杂志》,在1999年该杂志最后一期以专辑形式专题研究了行为金融学。

Behavioral Finance 行为金融学

Behavioral Finance 行为金融学
Investors need more premium to invest in riskier assets
News is not immediately reflected in forecasts
Equity Premium Puzzle
Overreaction & Availability Bias
• If they continue to act based on their biases, they will eventually be driven out of the market
• But: Sheer luck may enable them to stay in the market
• Prospect Theory
• Allais Paradox
• Recency Effect • Overreaction & Availability Bias
• E.G. Werner De Bondt and Richard Thaler - "Does the Market Overreact?“
• Herd Behavior
• Gamble Fallacy • Confirmation Biases • Mental Accounting • Anchoring
• E.G. Kanheman & Tversky - “Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics And Biases”
Stocks are screened for growth and value characteristics
7.00% 6.00% 5.00% 4.00% 3.00% 2.00% 1.00% 0.00% -1.00% -2.00% -3.00%

行为金融学理论(Behavioralfinancetheory)

行为金融学理论(Behavioralfinancetheory)

行为金融学理论(Behavioral finance theory)The modern financial theory classic that people's decisions are based on rational expectations (Rational Expectation), risk avoidance (Risk Aversion), the utility maximization and constantly update their knowledge and decision making assumptions, but a lot of psychological research shows that people's actual investment decision is not so. Secondly, the modern financial theory and the efficient market hypothesis is established on the basis of effective competition in the market, and a large number of studies show that non rational investors often can obtain higher returns than investors. Behavioral finance is based on this kind of market vision, and develops a new financial study using the psychological study of people's actual decision-making process.Behavioral finance studies the mispricing of investment in the investment market due to its own investment behavior, and the resulting behavioral anomaly is the place where Alfa (beyond the market rate of return) is generated. Experts on behavioral finance more, managers have more chances to find Alfa, but also the financial behavior so the seed and buried self destruction, Alfa in the market is less, the market will become more effective, and behavioral anomalies in the market less, then study the financial financial will have no need to there. Second, the more managers who want to beat the market, the harder they work, the more effective the market will become and the less likely it will be to beat the market.The emergence of 4.3.1. behavioral financeAs early as 1950s, people began to study behavioral economics,but earlier studies were rather scattered. It was not until 1970s that Kahneman (Daniel Kahneman) and Tversky (Amos Tversky) conducted extensive and systematic research on this field. Behavioral economics emphasizes that people's behavior is not only driven by interest, but also influenced by many psychological factors. The prospect theory combines psychological research and economic research effectively, reveals the decision-making mechanism under uncertainty, and opens up a completely new research field.4.3.2. is a leading representative of behavioral financeKahneman, the founder of Behavioral Finance (Daniel Kahneman) in 1934 was born in Israel in 1954, graduated from the Hebrew University, and in 1961 obtained a doctorate in psychology at the University of California, after the turn at the Hebrew University faculty. Another creator Tversky (Amos Tversky) was born on 1937 in Israel, has been at the University of Michigan studied philosophy and psychology at the Hebrew University, after graduation, here met his best partner Kahneman, which opened their lifelong friendship and excellence in academic research, and in 1979 jointly issued the basic theory of "behavioral finance prospect theory" (Prospect Theory). Later, he went to the University of California at Berkeley in the United States, and he went to Standford in the United states.Kahneman because of the prospect theory of behavioral finance contribution in 2002 received the Nobel Prize in economics, but it is a pity but Tversky in 6 years ago (1996 years) died, only 59 years old, can not wait for the arrival of honor.4.3.3. behavioral finance, major perspectivesBehavioral finance mainly puts forward two theories:A. BSV (Barberis, Shlefer, and, Vishny, 1998),B. DHS (Daniel, Hirsheifer, and, Subramanyam, 1998).First, the BSV theory holds that returns are stochastic, but the general investor erroneously believes that there are two paradigms for income change:Paradigm A: investors think that earnings change is mean reversion, and stock volatility is only a temporary phenomenon, and does not need to adjust its behavior according to changes in income. This behavior will cause investors to respond to the expected lack of earnings, and when the actual earnings do not match the expectations, they will be adjusted, so that changes in the stock price reaction to changes in earnings lags behind.Paradigm B: investors think that changes in earnings tend to be trend, and share prices have the same direction and continuous effects on earnings. Such investors tend to tend to expand the trend by mistake and overreact to changes in earnings.Second, DHS theory divides investors into two categories: one is the information one, the other is the non information. Without information, its investment behavior will not be affected by the judgment bias, and the information can be easily affected by the judgment bias.The DHS model divides the judgment bias of the information into two categories: one is overconfidence, and the other is biased self attribution (self-contribution). Overconfidence leads investors to exaggerate the accuracy of their stock valuation; biased self attribution leads investors to underestimate the impact of public information on stock value. That is to say, when the investor pursues this model, it will lead to the deviation between the personal information and the public information,This divergence leads to short-term continuity and long-term support for share prices.4.3.4. main behavioral finance modelUnder the framework of the two kinds of BSV and DHS, put forward the prospect theory of Behavioral Finance (Prospect Theory), behavioral portfolio theory (Behavioral Portfolio Theory) and the behavior asset pricing model (Behavioral BAPM Asset Pricing Model) on behavioral finance model.A. prospect theoryTheory (Prospect) combines psychological research and economic research effectively, reveals the decision-making mechanism under uncertainty, and opens up a whole new research field. In this sense, Kahneman's award may change the direction of future economics.In general, the prospect theory has the following three basicprinciple: (a) the majority of people in the face of the time are risk averse; (b) the majority of people in the face of loss when the risk preference; (c) are more sensitive to losses than get.Law of prospect theory: people are often cautious and unwilling to take risks when they are faced with them, while everyone is an adventurer in the face of losses. In the face of the time to avoid risks, and in the face of preference for the risk of loss, and the loss and the gain is relative to the reference point for the change, people use things in the evaluation point of view, can change people's attitude toward risk.The law of prospect theory two: People's sensitivity to loss and gain is different, and the pain of loss is far greater than that of happiness. In the 1992 study, Tversky and Kahneman found that people usually needed two times the loss of earnings to make up for the pain caused by the loss.B. behavioral portfolio theoryThe combination theory of BPT (Behavioral Portfolio Theory) behavior of assets, in 1985 by Shefrin and Statman put forward the theory that Pyramid investors have layered structure of the portfolio, each layer corresponds to the specific investment objectives and risk investors. Some of the money is invested at the bottom of the safest, and some funds are invested in more risky higher ups, with correlations between layers.Relatively speaking, the traditional portfolio theory to portfolio as a whole, and it is assumed that only the covariancebetween different securities account in building the portfolio, and are risk averse investors, and this behavior in real life is not entirely consistent.C. behavioral asset pricing modelBehavioral Model BAPM (Behavioral Asset Pricing asset pricing) investors are divided into information traders and noise traders. Information traders are rational investors who support the CAPM model of modern financial theory, avoid cognitive errors, and have variance preferences. Noise traders are apt to make conscious errors and have no strict variance preferences.When the information traders occupy the main body of the market, the market is efficient; when the noise traders occupy the market main body, the market is inefficient. In BAPM, the returns on securities are determined by the "Behavioral Beta", where the market portfolio is more representative. For example, noise traders tend to overestimate the price of growth stocks, and the proportion of growth stocks in the corresponding market is higher, because the behavioral portfolio is proportional to the market mix and the proportion of mature stocks should be raised.Statman further pointed out that the decision to supply and demand is people's utilitarian considerations (product costs, alternatives, prices, etc.) and value expression considerations (personal tastes, special preferences, etc.). CAPM includes only utilitarian considerations, while BAPM includes both. Due to the characteristics of BAPM value, andthe utilitarian characteristics, therefore, it is effective to accept a market from can't beat the market, on the other hand, from the meaning of rationalism of refuse market efficiency, the future development of finance has a profound revelation.In short, the behavioral finance through questioning on modern financial core hypothesis "theory of rational people", put forward the prospect theory, utility function of investors is concave function, and face the loss of utility function is a convex function. In financial transactions, investors psychological factors will make the actual decision-making process of optimal decision process is described from the classical finance theory, and system of rational deviation, and not because of the statistical average and eliminate.The investment strategies based on behavioral finance include average capital strategy, time diversification strategy, contrarian investment strategy and inertial investment strategy.4.3.5. behavioral finance explains the main behavioral anomalies in the marketA. overreactionPeople are too sensitive to asset prices, information conferences make people overreact, resulting in excessive or falling securities prices.B. disposition effectDue to the cognitive bias of investors,For the performance of the investment profit and loss of certainty ". The" loss aversion of the heart ", reflected in the behavior for selling profitable stocks to sell, easy to be a losing stock phenomenon, resulting in the relatively long time firmly.C. noise tradingShort - term investors and noise traders in the market have their own information. In his collection of information, by which investors more specific information, the more likely he is to profit, and such information may be associated with the basic value of information, also may be unrelated with the basic value of noise, which is called the information aggregation positive spillover effect. This effect may make the traders who obtain new information can not get the corresponding return, which is not conducive to the collection of information and the allocation of resources.D. herd effectInvestors are affected and imitated by other investors under the influence of uncertain information. That is, "all investors run in the same direction, and no one struggles with the overwhelming majority of people."."There are two main herding effects in the stock market:The first is the information based herd effectComplete information is a premise hypothesis of neo classical finance theory, but in fact, even in the modern society where information is highly disseminated, information is inadequate. In the case of insufficient information, investors do not make decisions entirely on the basis of their own information decisions, but on the basis of other people's investment behavior. The herding performance is "follow suit" or "the village" phenomenon.The second is the reputation based and reward based herd effectThis effect is most common in the fund manager, because employers do not understand the fund managers, fund managers do not understand their own investment capacity, in order to avoid investment mistakes and reputation risks and their remuneration, fund managers have motivation to mimic other fund managers' investment behavior. If many fund managers take the same action, the herd effect will emerge.。

【推荐下载】关于行为金融学综述

【推荐下载】关于行为金融学综述

关于行为金融学综述行为金融学综述如下文行为金融学(behavioral finance,BF)作为新兴的金融学分支与占据金融学统治地位已经有三十年之久的有效市场假说(efficient market hypothesis,EMH),对金融学的基础套利,投资人理性以及自1980 年代以来涌现出来的大量异常现象进行了达二十年之长的争论,双方此消彼长,加深了人们对金融市场的理解,促进了金融学向更广更深的方向发展。

一、介绍在传统金融学的范式中,理性意味着两个方面:首先,代理人的信仰是正确的:他们用于预测未知变量未来实现的主观分布就是那些被抽取实现的分布。

其次,给定他们的信仰,在与Savage 的主观期望效用(SEU)概念相一致的意义上,代理人做出正常可接受的选择。

BF 是一种研究金融市场崭新方法,至少部分地以对传统范例面临的困难做出反应的面貌出现的。

广义上,BF 认为通过使用某些代理人不是完全理性的模型,可以更好的理解某些金融现象。

在某些行为金融学模型中,代理人的信仰不完全正确,大都是因为不恰当的应用贝叶斯法则。

在另一些模型中,代理人的信仰是正确的但做出的选择通常是有疑问的,与SEU 不相容。

BF 最大的成功之一是一系列理论文章表明在理性交易者和非理性交易者相互影响的经济体中,非理性对价格的影响是实质性的和长期的。

文献称之为套利限制(limits of arbitrage) ,这构成了BF 的两大块之一。

(见第二部分)为了做出清晰的预测,行为模型常需要指定代理人的非理性形式。

人们究竟怎样误用贝叶斯法则或偏离SEU 呢?在此引导下,行为经济学家们典型地求助于认知心理学家汇编的大量实验证据,这些都是关于人们形成信仰时潜在的偏误,和人们的偏好或给定信仰后怎样做出决策的。

因此心理学构成了BF 的第二大块。

(见第三部分)我们考虑BF 的特殊应用:理解整个股市,平均回报的横截面情况,封闭式基金定价;理解投资者特殊群体怎样选择其资产组合和跨时交易;理解证券发行,资本结构和公司的股利政策。

基于行为金融学分析公司理财的综述(定稿)

基于行为金融学分析公司理财的综述(定稿)

基于行为金融学分析公司理财的综述摘要:现代金融学以严密的逻辑和数学推理建立起庞大的理论大厦, Markowitz的投资组合理论,Modigliani—Miller的MM理论,SharPe等人的资本资产定价理论,Fama的有效市场理论,Black—Scholes—Merton的期权定价理论和Ross的套利定价理论等都在公司理财中起到了非常重要的地位,成为现代金融学的理论基础。

但在20世纪80年代中期以后,金融市场上日历效应、IPO 溢价、封闭式基金之迷等异象不断出现,传统金融理论对此已经无法解释。

越来越多的学者开始修正传统理论的假设,行为金融学理论悄然兴起。

行为金融学(behavioral finance,BF)是金融学、心理学、行为学、社会学等学科相交叉的边缘学科,它从微观个体行为以及产生这种行为的心理等动因来解释、研究和预测金融市场的发展。

本文将着眼于筹资、投资、融资、收益分配四个角度,以行为金融学的理论来探讨和解释公司理财行为。

以期为所有关注行为金融学的人士提供一些研究参考。

关键字:行为金融学、公司理财、筹资、投资、融资、收益分配正文:行为金融学对支撑传统金融学最基本的根基——理性人假说、有效市场假说提出了质疑,并以此为起点,对公司理财中一些基础性、奠基性理论进行了质疑与改进。

一、行为金融学对于传统金融学根基的质疑(一)人并非完全理性根据有效市场假说的观点,人是完全理性的,投资者是风险厌恶的,他们总会根据期望效用最大化和贝叶斯法则进行决策。

然而事实并非如此,Kahneman 和Tversky(1973)的研究指出,投资者在决策时,并不遵循期望效用最大化原则,他们并不看重决策最终获得财富的绝对水平,而更加在意以某参照点为标准的相对财富的变化状况;Kahneman和Tversky(1979)进一步研究表明,投资者并不是风险厌恶者,而是损失厌恶者。

Van Raaii(1981)提出的“经济心理学”更表明,当经济环境反应出一般经济状况的改变时,由于个人因素的差异,不同的人对经济情况会有不同的认知与感受,加上个人主观的价值判断,进而通过行为表现而与经济环境产生复杂的互动关系。

行为金融论文范文精选3篇(全文)

行为金融论文范文精选3篇(全文)

行为金融论文范文精选3篇1文献综述一般认为,行为金融学的产生以1951年Burrel教授发表《投资战略的实验方法的可能性研究》一文为标志,该文首次将行为心理学结合在经济学中来解释金融现象。

1972年,Slovic 教授和Bumn教授合写了《人类决策的心理学研究》,为行为金融学理论作出了开创性的贡献。

1979年DnielKhnemn教授和mosTversky教授发表了《预期理论:风险决策分析》,正是提出了行为金融学中的预期理论。

中南大学的饶育蕾和刘达锋著的《行为金融学》是我国第一本系统阐述行为金融学理论的著作。

吴世农、俞乔、王庆石和刘颖等早在ZG证券市场初建时就对ZG股市调查并进行取样分析,得出ZG市场为非有效市场,其主要论文有:吴世农、韦绍永的《股市投资组合规模和风险关系的实证研究》,陈旭、刘勇的《对我国股票市场有效性的实证分析及队策建议》。

国内对这一理论的研究相对不足,对投资策略的涉足更是有限。

本文主要是借鉴了两位美国学者的思路进行论证。

美国学者彼得L伯恩斯坦和阿斯瓦斯达摩达兰著的《投资治理》总结了美国比较有影响力的观点,对行为金融学理论在投资领域的应用进行了进展,对投资行为进行了全面剖析,其对投资策略的研究更具有独到之处,这种在行为金融学下投资策略的研究对我国证券业的进展将有十分重要的借鉴意义。

罗伯特泰戈特著《投资治理-保证有效投资的25歌法则》以其简单而明了的笔法描绘了行为金融学下投资方法的选择应具备的条件和原则,指导我们的实践。

BrighmEhrhrot著的《财务治理理论与实务》中也不乏对行为金融学的应用,比如:选择权的应用等。

2行为金融学概述行为金融学是将行为学、心理学和认知学成果运用到金融市场上产生的一种新理论,是基于心理学实验结果提出投资者决策时的心理特征假设来研究投资者实际投资决策行为的一门学科。

行为金融学有两个研究主题:一是市场并非有效,主要探讨金融噪声理论;二是投资者并非是理性的,主要探讨投资者会发生的各种认知和行为偏差问题。

行为金融学复习资料Behavioral finance博迪投资学

行为金融学复习资料Behavioral finance博迪投资学

行为金融学的理论架构
预测错误 信息处理偏差 认知心理学 框定偏差
过度自信
保守主义 忽视样本规模和代表性
套利限制
心理账户 决策偏差 后悔规避
前景理论
认知心理学和套利限制构成了行为金融的两大根基。 行为金融学发展到今日,累积了许多独特的分析范式,但是,仍旧没有形成一个系统的理论,不同的行为 金融学家发表的理论比较分散
市场是否有效
传统金融理论的基石——有效市场假说(EMH) - 1) 信息是无成本的 - 2) 所有交易者同时接受信息 - 3) 所有市场的参与者都是理性的,并且追求效用的最大化。 行为金融学认为: - 1) 在现实的金融市场上,交易者行为和市场的信息特征是完全不同的 - 2) 证券价格没有反映全部的相关信息 - 3) 投资者的信息是不完备的和不对称的 - 4) 内幕信息可以给内幕交易人带来收益 - 5) 信息对搜集者具有相当的价值,这种套利就是有成本和风险的 - 6) 因而市场是无效的
ZHOU RUOQIAN
忽视样本规模和代表性: 投资者基于小样本过快地推出一种模式,并推断出未来的趋势。
决策偏差
即使给定未来收益的概率分布,投资者做出的决策通常是前后矛盾或次优的。 - 结果: 行为偏差 框定偏差: 风险是如何描述的,是“面临有风险的可能损失”还是“面临有风险的可能收益”,可能会影 响到投资者的决策。 心理账户: 投资者会根据风险-报酬将账户或资金分成不同部分,他们不愿动用原有资本。 后悔规避: 投资者不依惯例进行决策并出现不利结果时会更后悔。 前景理论:效用取决于财富水平的变化量。
信息处理偏差
投资者通常不能正确处理信息。 - 结果:不能正确推断未来收益的概率分布。
1/6
CMA: Behavioral Finance 预测错误: 过于依赖近期经验。 过度自信:投资者高估自己的信念和预测的准确性。 保守主义: 投资者对最近出现的事件反应太慢,对新发布的消息反应不足。
  1. 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
  2. 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
  3. 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。

Behavioral Corporate Finance: A Survey∗Malcolm BakerHarvard Business School and NBERmbaker@Richard S. RubackHarvard Business Schoolrruback@Jeffrey WurglerNYU Stern School of Business and NBERjwurgler@October 9, 2004AbstractResearch in behavioral corporate finance takes two distinct approaches. The first emphasizes that investors are less than fully rational. It views managerial financing and investment decisions as rational responses to securities market mispricing. The second approach emphasizes that managers are less than fully rational. It studies the effect of nonstandard preferences and judgmental biases on managerial decisions. This survey reviews the theory, empirical challenges, and current evidence pertaining to each approach. Overall, the behavioral approaches help to explain a number of important financing and investment patterns. The survey closes with a list of open questions.∗ This article will appear in the Handbook in Corporate Finance: Empirical Corporate Finance, which is edited by Espen Eckbo. The authors are grateful to Heitor Almeida, Nick Barberis, Zahi Ben-David, Espen Eckbo, Xavier Gabaix, Dirk Jenter, Augustin Landier, Alexander Ljungqvist, Hersh Shefrin, Andrei Shleifer, Meir Statman, and Theo Vermaelen for helpful comments. Baker and Ruback gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Division of Research of the Harvard Business School.Table of ContentsI. Introduction (1)II. The irrational investors approach (4)A. Theoretical framework (6)B. Empirical challenges (10)C. Investment policy (13)C.1. Real investment (14)C.2. Mergers and acquisitions (16)C.3. Diversification and focus (18)D. Financial policy (19)D.1. Equity issues (19)D.2. Repurchases (23)D.3. Debt issues (24)D.4. Cross-border issues (26)D.5. Capital structure (27)E. Other corporate decisions (28)E.1. Dividends (29)E.2. Firm names (31)E.3. Earnings management (32)E.4. Executive compensation (33)III. The irrational managers approach (34)A. Theoretical framework (36)B. Empirical challenges (39)C. Investment policy (40)C.1. Real investment (40)C.2. Mergers and acquisitions (42)D. Financial policy (43)D.1. Capital structure (43)D.2. Financial contracting (44)E. Other behavioral patterns (44)E.1. Bounded rationality (45)E.2. Reference-point preferences (46)IV. Conclusion (48)References (51)I. IntroductionCorporate finance aims to explain the financial contracts and the real investment behavior that emerge from the interaction of managers and investors. Thus, a complete explanation of financing and investment patterns requires an understanding of the beliefs and preferences of these two sets of agents. The majority of research in corporate finance assumes a broad rationality. Agents are supposed to develop unbiased forecasts about future events and use these to make decisions that best serve their own interests. As a practical matter, this means that managers can take for granted that capital markets are efficient, with prices rationally reflecting public information about fundamental values. Likewise, investors can take for granted that managers will act in their self-interest, rationally responding to incentives shaped by compensation contracts, the market for corporate control, and other governance mechanisms.This paper surveys research in behavioral corporate finance. This research replaces the traditional rationality assumptions with potentially more realistic behavioral assumptions. The literature is divided into two general approaches, and we organize the survey around them. Roughly speaking, the first approach emphasizes the effect of investor behavior that is less than fully rational, and the second considers managerial behavior that is less than fully rational. For each line of research, we review the basic theoretical frameworks, the main empirical challenges, and the empirical evidence. Of course, in practice, both channels of irrationality may operate at the same time; our taxonomy is meant to fit the existing literature, but it does suggest some structure for how one might, in the future, go about combining the two approaches.The “irrational investors approach” assumes that securities market arbitrage is imperfect, and thus that prices can be too high or too low. Rational managers are assumed to perceive mispricings, and to make decisions that may encourage or respond to mispricing. While theirdecisions may maximize the short-run value of the firm, they may also result in lower long-run values as prices correct. In the simple theoretical framework we outline, managers balance three objectives: fundamental value, catering, and market timing. Maximizing fundamental value has the usual ingredients. Catering refers to any actions intended to boost share prices above fundamental value. Market timing refers specifically to financing decisions intended to capitalize on temporary mispricings, generally via the issuance of overvalued securities and the repurchase of undervalued ones.Empirical tests of the irrational investors model face a significant challenge: measuring mispricing. We discuss how this issue has been tackled and the ambiguities that remain. Overall, despite some unresolved questions, the evidence suggests that the irrational investors approach has a considerable degree of descriptive power. We review studies on investment behavior, merger activity, the clustering and timing of corporate security offerings, capital structure, corporate name changes, dividend policy, earnings management, and other managerial decisions. We also identify some disparities between the theory and the evidence. For example, while catering to fads has potential to reduce long-run value, the literature has yet to clearly document significant long-term value losses.The second approach to behavioral corporate finance, the “irrational managers approach,” is less developed at this point. It assumes that managers have behavioral biases, but retains the rationality of investors, albeit limiting the governance mechanisms they can employ to constrain managers. Following the emphasis of the current literature, our discussion centers on the biases of optimism and overconfidence. A simple model shows how these biases, in leading managers to believe their firms are undervalued, encourage overinvestment from internal resources, and a preference for internal to external finance, especially internal equity. We note that the predictionsof the optimism and overconfidence models typically look very much like those of agency and asymmetric information models.In this approach, the main obstacles for empirical tests include distinguishing predictions from standard, non-behavioral models, as well as empirically measuring managerial biases. Again, however, creative solutions have been proposed. The effects of optimism and overconfidence have been empirically studied in the context of merger activity, corporate investment-cash flow relationships, entrepreneurial financing and investment decisions, and the structure of financial contracts. Separately, we discuss the potential of a few other behavioral patterns that have received some attention in corporate finance, including bounded rationality and reference-point preferences. As in the case of investor irrationality, the real economic losses associated with managerial irrationality have yet to be clearly quantified, but some evidence suggests that they are very significant.Taking a step back, it is important to note that the two approaches take very different views about the role and quality of managers, and have very different normative implications as a result. That is, when the primary source of irrationality is on the investor side, long-term value maximization and economic efficiency requires insulating managers from short-term share price pressures. Managers need to be insulated to achieve the flexibility necessary to make decisions that may be unpopular in the marketplace. This may imply benefits from internal capital markets, barriers to takeovers, and so forth. On the other hand, if the main source of irrationality is on the managerial side, efficiency requires reducing discretion and obligating managers to respond to market price signals. The stark contrast between the normative implications of these two approaches to behavioral corporate finance is one reason why the area is fascinating, and why more work in the area is needed.Overall, our survey suggests that the behavioral approaches can help to explain a range of financing and investment patterns, while at the same time depend on a relatively small set of realistic assumptions. Moreover, there is much room to grow before the field reaches maturity. In an effort to stimulate that growth, we close the survey with a short list of open questions.II. The irrational investors approachWe start with one extreme, in which rational managers coexist with irrational investors. There are two key building blocks here. First, irrational investors must influence securities prices. This requires limits on arbitrage. Second, managers must be smart in the sense of being able to distinguish market prices and fundamental value.The literature on market inefficiency is far too large to survey here. It includes such phenomena as the January effect; the effect of trading hours on price volatility; post-earnings-announcement drift; momentum; delayed reaction to news announcements; positive autocorrelation in earnings announcement effects; Siamese twin securities that have identical cash flows but trade at different prices, negative “stub” values; closed-end fund pricing patterns; bubbles and crashes in growth stocks; related evidence of mispricing in options, bond, and foreign exchange markets; and so on. These patterns, and the associated literature on arbitrage costs and risks, for instance short-sales constraints, that facilitate mispricings, are surveyed by Barberis and Thaler (2003) and Shleifer (2000). In the interest of space, we refer the reader to these excellent sources, and for the discussion of this section we simply take as given that mispricings can and do occur.But even if capital markets are inefficient, why assume that corporate managers are “smart” in the sense of being able to identify mispricing? One can offer several justifications.First, corporate managers have superior information about their own firm. This is underscored by the evidence that managers earn abnormally high returns on their own trades, as in Muelbroek (1992), Seyhun (1992), or Jenter (2004). Managers can also create an information advantage by managing earnings, a topic to which we will return, or with the help of conflicted analysts, as for example in Bradshaw, Richardson, and Sloan (2003).Second, corporate managers also have fewer constraints than equally “smart” money managers. Consider two well-known models of limited arbitrage: DeLong, Shleifer, Summers, and Waldmann (1990) is built on short horizons and Miller (1977) on short-sales constraints. CFOs tend to be judged on longer horizon results than are money managers, allowing them to take a view on market valuations in a way that money managers cannot.1 Also, short-sales constraints prevent money managers from mimicking CFOs. When a firm or a sector becomes overvalued, corporations are the natural candidates to expand the supply of shares. Money managers are not.Third and finally, managers might just follow intuitive rules of thumb that allow them to identify mispricing even without a real information advantage. In Baker and Stein (2004), one such successful rule of thumb is to issue equity when the market is particularly liquid, in the sense of a small price impact upon the issue announcement. In the presence of short-sales constraints, unusually high liquidity is a symptom of the fact that the market is dominated by irrational investors, and hence is overvalued.1 For example, suppose a manager issues equity at $50 per share. Now if those shares subsequently double, the manager might regret not delaying the issue, but he will surely not be fired, having presided over a rise in the stock price. In contrast, imagine a money manager sells (short) the same stock at $50. This might lead to considerable losses, an outflow of funds, and, if the bet is large enough, perhaps the end of a career.A. Theoretical frameworkWe use the assumptions of inefficient markets and smart managers to develop a simple theoretical framework for the irrational investors approach. The framework has roots in Fischer and Merton (1984), De Long, Shleifer, Summers, and Waldmann (1989), Morck, Shleifer, and Vishny (1990b), and Blanchard, Rhee, and Summers (1993), but our particular derivation borrows most from Stein (1996).In the irrational investors approach, the manager balances three conflicting goals. The first is to maximize fundamental value. This means selecting and financing investment projects to increase the rationally risk-adjusted present value of future cash flows. To simplify the analysis, we do not explicitly model taxes, costs of financial distress, agency problems or asymmetric information. Instead, we specify fundamental value as()Kf−⋅,,Kwhere f is increasing and concave in new investment K. To the extent that any of the usual market imperfections leads the Modigliani-Miller (1958) theorem to fail, financing may enter f alongside investment.The second goal is to maximize the current share price of the firm’s securities. In perfect capital markets, the first two objectives are the same, since the definition of market efficiency is that prices equal fundamental value. But once one relaxes the assumption of investor rationality, this need not be true, and the second objective is distinct. In particular, the second goal is to “cater” to short-term investor demands via particular investment projects or otherwise packaging the firm and its securities in a way that maximizes appeal to investors. Through such catering activities, managers influence the temporary mispricing, which we represent by the function ()⋅δ,where the arguments of δ depend on the nature of investor sentiment. The arguments might include investing in a particular technology, assuming a conglomerate or single-segment structure, changing the corporate name, managing earnings, initiating a dividend, and so on. In practice, the determinants of mispricing may well vary over time.The third goal is to exploit the current mispricing for the benefit of existing, long-run investors. This is done by a “market timing” financing policy whereby managers supply securities that are temporarily overvalued and repurchase those that are undervalued. Such a policy transfers value from the new or the outgoing investors to the ongoing, long-run investors; the transfer is realized as prices correct in the long run.2 For simplicity, we focus here on temporary mispricing in the equity markets, and so δ refers to the difference between the current price and the fundamental value of equity. More generally, each of the firm’s securities may be mispriced to some degree. By selling a fraction of the firm e, long run shareholders gain ()⋅δe.We leave out the budget constraint, lumping together the sale of new and existing shares. Instead of explicitly modeling the flow of funds and any potential financial constraints, we will consider the reduced form impact of e on fundamental value.It is worth noting that other capital market imperfections can lead to a sort of catering behavior. For example, reputation models in the spirit of Holmstrom (1982) can lead to earnings management, inefficient investment, and excessive swings in corporate strategy even when the capital markets are not fooled in equilibrium.3 Viewed in this light, the framework here is2 Of course, we are also using the market inefficiency assumption here in assuming that managerial efforts to capturea mispricing do not completely destroy it in the process, as they would in the rational expectations world of Myers and Majluf (1984). In other words, investors underreact to corporate decisions designed to exploit mispricing. This leads to some testable implications, as we discuss below.3 For examples, see Stein (1989) and Scharfstein and Stein (1990). For a comparison of rational expectations and inefficient markets in this framework, see Aghion and Stein (2004).relaxing the assumptions of rational expectations in Holmstrom, in the case of catering, and Myers and Majluf (1984), in the case of market timing.Putting the goals of fundamental value, catering, and market timing into one objective function, the irrational investors approach has the manager choosing investment and financing to()()[]()()⋅−+⋅+−⋅δλδλ1,max ,e K K f eK , where λ, between zero and one, specifies the manager’s horizon. When λ equals one, the manager cares only about creating value for existing, long-run shareholders, the last term drops out, and there is no distinct impact of catering. However, even an extreme long-horizon manager cares about short-term mispricing for the purposes of market timing, and thus may cater to short-term mispricing to further this objective. With a shorter horizon, maximizing the stock price becomes an objective in its own right, even without any concomitant equity issues.We take the managerial horizon as given, exogenously set by personal characteristics, career concerns, and the compensation contract. If the manager plans to sell equity or exercise options in the near term, his portfolio considerations may lower λ. However, managerial horizon may also be endogenous. For instance, consider a venture capitalist who recognizes a bubble. He might offer a startup manager a contract that loads heavily on options and short-term incentives, since he cares less about valuations that prevail beyond the IPO lock-up period. Career concerns and the market for corporate control can also combine to shorten horizons, since if the manager does not maximize short-run prices, the firm may be acquired and the manager fired.Differentiating with respect to K and e gives the optimal investment and financial policy of a rational manager operating in inefficient capital markets:()()()⋅+−=⋅−K K e K f δλλ11,, and ()()()()⋅++⋅=⋅−−e e e K f δδλλ1,.In words, the first condition is about investment policy. The marginal value created from investment is weighed against the standard cost of capital, normalized to be one here, net of the impact that this incremental investment has on mispricing, and hence its effect through mispricing on catering and market timing gains. The second condition is about financing. The marginal value lost from shifting the firm’s current capital structure toward equity is weighed against the direct market timing gains and the impact that this incremental equity issuance has on mispricing, and hence its effect on catering and market timing gains. This is a lot to swallow at once, so we consider some special cases.Investment policy. Investment and financing are separable if both δK and f e are equal to zero. Then the investment decision reduces to the familiar perfect markets condition of f K equal to unity. Real consequences of mispricing for investment thus arise in two ways. In Stein (1996) and Baker, Stein, and Wurgler (2003), f e is not equal to zero. There is an optimal capital structure, or at least an upper bound on debt capacity. The benefits of issuing or repurchasing equity in response to mispricing are balanced against the reduction in fundamental value that arises from too much (or possibly too little) leverage. In Polk and Sapienza (2004) and Gilchrist, Himmelberg, and Huberman (2004), there is no optimal capital structure, but δK is not equal to zero: mispricing is itself a function of investment. Polk and Sapienza focus on catering effects and do not consider financing (e equal to zero in this setup), while Gilchrist et al. model the market timing decisions of managers with long horizons (λ equal to one).Financial policy. The demand curve for a firm’s equity slopes down under the natural assumption that δe is negative, e.g., issuing shares partly corrects mispricing.4 When investment and financing are separable, managers act like monopolists. This is easiest to see when managers 4 Gilchrist et al. (2004) model this explicitly with heterogeneous investor beliefs and short-sales constraints.have long horizons, and they sell down the demand curve until marginal revenue δ is equal to marginal cost –e δe . Note that price remains above fundamental value even after the issue: “corporate arbitrage” moves the market toward, but not all the way to, market efficiency.5 Managers sell less equity when they care about short-run stock price (λ less than one, here). For example, in Ljungqvist, Nanda, and Singh (2004), managers expect to sell their own shares soon after the IPO and so issue less as a result. Managers also sell less equity when there are costs of suboptimal leverage.Other corporate decisions. Managers do more than simply invest and issue equity, and this framework can be expanded to accommodate other decisions. Consider dividend policy. Increasing or initiating a dividend may simultaneously affect both fundamental value, through taxes, and the degree of mispricing, if investors categorize stocks according to payout policy as they do in Baker and Wurgler (2004a). The tradeoff is()()()⋅+=⋅−−d d e K f δλλ1,, where the left-hand side is the tax cost of dividends, for example, and the right-hand side is the market timing gain, if the firm is simultaneously issuing equity, plus the catering gain, if the manager has short horizons. In principle, a similar tradeoff governs the earnings management decision or corporate name changes; however, in the latter case, the fundamental costs of catering would presumably be small.B. Empirical challengesThe framework outlined above suggests a role for securities mispricing in investment, financing, and other corporate decisions. The main challenge for empirical tests in this area is 5 Total market timing gains may be even higher in a dynamic model where managers can sell in small increments down the demand curve.measuring mispricing, which by its nature is hard to pin down. Researchers have found several ways to operationalize empirical tests, but none of them is perfect.Ex ante misvaluation. One option is to take an ex ante measure of mispricing, for instance a scaled-price ratio in which a market value in the numerator is related to some measure of fundamental value in the denominator. Perhaps the most common choice is the market-to-book ratio: A high market-to-book suggests that the firm may be overvalued. Consistent with this idea, and the presumption that mispricing corrects in the long run, market-to-book is found to be inversely related to future stock returns in the cross-section by Fama and French (1992) and in the time-series by Kothari and Shanken (1997) and Pontiff and Schall (1998). Also, extreme values of market-to-book are connected to extreme investor expectations by Lakonishok, Shleifer and Vishny (1994), La Porta (1996), and La Porta, Lakonishok, Shleifer, and Vishny (1997).One difficulty that arises with this approach is that the market-to-book ratio or another ex ante measure of mispricing may be correlated with an array of firm characteristics. Book value is not a precise estimate of fundamental value, but rather a summary of past accounting performance. Thus, firms with excellent growth prospects tend to have high market-to-book ratios, and those with agency problems might have low ratios—and perhaps these considerations, rather than mispricing, drive investment and financing decisions. Dong, Hirshleifer, Richardson, and Teoh (2003) and Ang and Cheng (2003) discount analyst earnings forecasts to construct an arguably less problematic measure of fundamentals than book value.Another factor that limits this approach is that a precise ex ante measure of mispricing would represent a profitable trading rule. There must be limits to arbitrage that prevent rational investors from fully exploiting such rules and trading away the information they contain about mispricing. But on a more positive note, the same intuition suggests that variables like market-to-book are likely to be a more reliable mispricing metric in regions of the data where short-sales constraints and other (measurable) arbitrage costs and risks are most severe. This observation has been exploited as an identification strategy.Ex post misvaluation. A second option is to use the information in future returns. The idea is that if stock prices routinely decline after a corporate event, one might infer that they were inflated at the time of the event. However, as detailed in Fama (1998) and Mitchell and Stafford (2000), this approach is also subject to several critiques.The most basic critique is the joint hypothesis problem: a predictable “abnormal” return might mean there was misvaluation ex ante, or simply that the definition of “normal” expected return (e.g., CAPM) is wrong. Perhaps the corporate event systematically coincides with changes in risk, and hence the return required in an efficient capital market. Another simple but important critique regards economic significance. Market value-weighting or focusing on NYSE/AMEX firms may reduce abnormal returns or cause them to disappear altogether.There are also statistical issues. For instance, corporate events are often clustered in time and by industry—IPOs are an example considered in Brav (2000)—and thus abnormal returns may not be independent. Barber and Lyon (1997) and Barber, Lyon, and Tsai (1999) show that inference with buy-and-hold returns (for each event) is challenging. Calendar-time portfolios, which consist of an equal- or value-weighted average of all firms making a given decision, have fewer problems here, but the changing composition of these portfolios adds another complication to standard tests. Loughran and Ritter (2000) also argue that such an approach is a less powerful test of mispricing, since the clustered events have the worst subsequent performance. A final statistical problem is that many studies cover only a short sample period. Schultz (2003) showsthat this can lead to a small sample bias if managers engage in “pseudo” market timing, making decisions in response to past rather than future price changes.Analyzing aggregate time series resolves some of these problems. Like the calendar time portfolios, time series returns are more independent. There are also established time-series techniques, e.g. Stambaugh (1999), to deal with small-sample biases. Nonetheless, the joint hypothesis problem remains, since rationally required returns may vary over time.But even when these econometric issues can be solved, interpretational issues may remain. For instance, suppose investors have a tendency to overprice firms that have genuinely good growth opportunities. If so, even investment that is followed by low returns need not be ex ante inefficient. Investment may have been responding to omitted measures of investment opportunities, not to the misvaluation itself.Cross-sectional interactions. Another identification strategy is to exploit the finer cross-sectional predictions of the theory. In this spirit, Baker, Stein, and Wurgler (2003) consider the prediction that if f e is positive, mispricing should be more relevant for financially constrained firms. More generally, managerial horizons or the fundamental costs of catering to sentiment may vary across firms in a measurable way. Of course, even in this approach, one still has to proxy for mispricing with an ex ante or ex post method. To the extent that the hypothesized cross-sectional pattern appears strongly in the data, however, objections about the measure of mispricing lose some steam.C. Investment policyOf paramount importance are the real consequences of market inefficiency. It is one thing to say that investor irrationality has an impact on capital market prices, or even financing policy,。

相关文档
最新文档